This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-08-372 
entitled 'Entitlement Reform Process: Other Countries' Experiences 
Provide Useful Insights for the United States' which was released on 
January 18, 2008.

This text file was formatted by the U.S. Government Accountability 
Office (GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part 
of a longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every 
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of 
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text 
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the 
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided 
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed 
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic 
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail 
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this 
document to Webmaster@gao.gov.

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work 
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the 
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this 
material separately.

Report to the Committee on the Budget, U.S. Senate:

United States Government Accountability Office: 
GAO:

January 2008:

Entitlement Reform Process:

Other Countries' Experiences Provide Useful Insights for the United 
States:

GAO-08-372: 

GAO Highlights:

Highlights of GAO-08-372, a report to the Committee on the Budget, U.S. 
Senate. 

Why GAO Did This Study:

Looking to the future, our nation faces large and growing structural 
deficits and escalating federal debt due primarily to rising health 
care costs and known demographic trends. Slowing the growth of 
entitlements is an essential part of the solution to these challenges. 

GAO was asked to identify useful insights from the entitlement reform 
processes in other countries. Specifically, GAO was asked to analyze 
(1) other countries’ major efforts to reform entitlement programs, (2) 
the pressure(s) that led countries to undertake the reforms, (3) how 
reform proposals were developed, and (4) to what extent enacted reforms 
built in triggers requiring future actions under certain conditions; 
and where such trigger mechanisms did not exist, whether some 
adjustments nonetheless occurred. 

GAO conducted a literature review focusing on developed, high-income 
Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development (OECD) countries 
facing similar fiscal challenges. To gain a more in-depth understanding 
of reform process, GAO selected three efforts for further study: 
Sweden’s pension reform in 1998, Germany’s pension reform in 2004, and 
the Netherlands’ disability reform in 2005. For these cases GAO 
interviewed government officials, reform participants, and experts 
knowledgeable about the reforms.

What GAO Found:

Other countries’ experiences suggest that reform of entitlement 
programs is difficult but also possible. Several countries more 
advanced in population aging and facing greater demographic challenges 
than ours have successfully undertaken reforms of major entitlement 
programs. Since the 1980s, almost all of the OECD countries have 
restructured their public pension programs; disability, unemployment, 
and other programs have also been reformed. Many reform efforts began 
or accelerated in an environment of economic and fiscal crisis. Other 
prompts included longer term concerns about population aging and 
economic competitiveness, and supranational factors such as a desire to 
meet the fiscal criteria for entry into the European Union. In many 
countries, reform occurred despite political processes that made it 
difficult. Consensus had to be built in coalition governments, and 
leaders had to work across parties to achieve a broad consensus for 
reform. 

Commissions were generally used to develop proposals, but this was only 
one stage in the reform process. Leaders needed to define the problem, 
persuading others that reform was needed and urgent. The challenge was 
to build a broad coalition to assure the reform’s permanency while 
preserving the main policy initiatives sought in the reform process.

* In some reform efforts political leaders used the “bully pulpit” to 
educate the public but in some cases commissions also helped. Achieving 
a broad consensus across parties and groups was key to enacting and 
sustaining reform. 

* Proposals were generally developed by ad hoc commissions established 
by governments with a strong commitment to reform. Commissions in case 
study efforts that developed proposals were small, with varying 
composition. They removed divisive issues from the usual political 
process, facilitating consultation and negotiation needed to devise a 
reform package. Commissions also helped to insulate policymakers from 
political risk. 

* Reform processes were generally complex and often conflict-ridden 
before they ultimately succeeded in enacting legislation. Many reforms 
were iterative. Following reform enactment, a need for additional 
changes sometimes emerged. 

* In some countries standing commissions were established to monitor 
pension systems and make recommendations for change. Some recent 
pension reforms have included mechanisms to automatically adjust 
benefits if adopted reforms prove insufficient to make programs 
sustainable.

What GAO Recommends: 

GAO is making no new recommendations in this report. 

To view the full product, including the scope and methodology, click on 
[hyperlink, http://www.GAO-08-372]. For more information, contact Susan 
J. Irving at (202) 512-9142 or irvings@gao.gov. 

[End of section] 

Contents: 

Letter:

Background:

Results in Brief:

Many Countries Have Reformed Entitlement Programs and Reform Efforts 
Continue:

A Variety of Pressures Have Led to Entitlement Reform in Other 
Countries:

How Reform Proposals Were Developed in Other Countries:

The Reform Process May Continue Following Enactment of Legislation:

Implications for the United States:

Appendix I: Scope and Methodology:

Appendix II: Summary of Selected U.S. Commissions:

Appendix III: Summary of Selected Reform Efforts:

Appendix IV: Pension Reform in Sweden:

Reform Overview: Significance of the Reform:

Origins of Reform:

The Reform Process:

Post-Reform Implementation and Adjustments:

Legacy of the Reform:

Appendix V: Disability Reform in the Netherlands:

Reform Overview: Significance of the Reform:

Disability in the Netherlands Differs from that in the United States:

Origins and History of Reform:

Structural Reform Implemented in 2006, Prompted by the Donner 
Commission:

Expectations: The Future of Reform:

Appendix VI: Pension Reform in Germany:

Reform Overview: Significance of the Reforms:

Origins and History of the Reforms:

The Reforms and the Public:

Expectations: The Future of Reform:

Appendix VII: GAO Contact and Staff Acknowledgments:

Table:

Table 1: Sweden's Public Pension System, Pre-and Post-Reform:

Figures:

Figure 1: Elderly Dependency Ratio for Selected High-Income Countries, 
1980 to 2020:

Figure 2: Public Spending on Old-Age and Survivors' Pensions in 
Selected High-Income Countries, 1990 and 2003:

Figure 3: Spending on Health Care as a Percent of GDP for Selected High-
Income Countries in 2005:

Figure 4: Key Events in Sweden's Pension Reform, 1982 through 2001:

Figure 5: Key Events in the Netherlands Disability Reform Process:

Figure 6: Disability Beneficiaries in the Netherlands: 1968 through 
2007:

Figure 7: Key Events in German Pension Reform Process: 

[End of section] 

United States Government Accountability Office: 
Washington, DC 20548:

January 18, 2008:

The Honorable Kent Conrad: 
Chairman: 
The Honorable Judd Gregg: 
Ranking Member: 
Committee on the Budget: 
United States Senate: 

Our nation faces a future fiscal challenge that poses severe and 
unacceptable risks to the federal budget and our economy. Absent policy 
change, in the future we face large and growing structural deficits and 
escalating federal debt due primarily to rising health care costs and 
known demographic trends. Continuing on this imprudent and 
unsustainable fiscal path will gradually erode, if not suddenly damage, 
our economy, our standard of living, and ultimately our national 
security. Unless action is taken, our current path will increasingly 
constrain our ability to address emerging and unexpected budgetary 
needs and increase the burdens that will be faced by our children, 
grandchildren, and future generations of Americans.

Taken together, Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid are the major 
drivers of our future fiscal challenge. While the appropriate level of 
revenues will be part of the debate about our fiscal future, making no 
changes to spending on Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid, and other 
drivers of the long-term fiscal gap would require ever-increasing tax 
levels-something that seems both inappropriate and implausible. 
Substantive reform of Social Security and our major health programs 
remains critical to recapturing our future fiscal flexibility.

Last year several proposals were made to establish special groups to 
help develop proposals for entitlement reforms to address the long-term 
fiscal challenge. On September 18, 2007, you jointly introduced a bill 
to establish a Bipartisan Task Force for Responsible Fiscal Action. 
Composed of Members of Congress and Administration officials, this 
group would be asked to make recommendations on how to significantly 
improve the government's long-term fiscal imbalances.[Footnote 1] 
Others have also introduced proposals to establish special groups with 
similar aims.[Footnote 2] At the Senate Budget Committee's October 31, 
2007, hearing on the Bipartisan Task Force proposal, I testified that 
this approach offers one potential means to achieve the objective of 
taking steps to make the tough choices that will be necessary to 
address the long-term fiscal challenge.[Footnote 3] As I have noted, 
revenues will also have to be on the table as we address the long-term 
fiscal challenge, but slowing the growth of entitlements is a necessary 
component of the solution. Accordingly, I have called for the 
establishment of a commission that would address the long-term fiscal 
challenge by developing proposals to put Social Security on a 
sustainable path and begin the reform of health care and the tax 
system.[Footnote 4]

You asked us to look at entitlement reforms in other countries with an 
eye to identifying useful insights and possible "lessons learned" from 
their reform process.

Specifically, you requested that we analyze:

(1) other countries' major efforts to reform entitlement programs,

(2) the pressure(s) that led countries to undertake the reforms,

(3) how reform proposals were developed (the structure or process used-
-e.g., commissions or special groups within the government), and:

(4) to what extent enacted reforms built in triggers requiring future 
actions under certain conditions; and where such trigger mechanisms did 
not exist, whether some adjustments nonetheless occurred.

We looked at the reform process in selected developed countries with a 
focus on instances where the reform process had included commissions or 
other special groups. We limited our review to developed, high-income 
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries 
facing similar but even more daunting long-term challenges and 
demographic changes than the United States. From our literature review 
we identified instances in other countries where enacted reforms to 
programs such as pension or other social welfare programs were expected 
or intended to slow cost growth and increase fiscal sustainability. 
Although OECD countries have made many reforms to their health care 
systems since the 1980s, and reform efforts continue, we found no 
country that has been able to optimize the multiple goals of cost 
containment, access, and quality over time. Some countries have already 
undertaken national pension reform efforts to address demographic 
changes similar to those occurring in the United States, and in a 
previously issued report we drew lessons from their 
experiences.[Footnote 5] Based on this, we selected three reform 
efforts for further study, including examples of both iterative and 
noniterative types of process: Sweden's pension reform in 1998; 
Germany's pension reform in 2004; and the Netherlands' disability 
reform in 2005. In these three cases we consulted with government 
officials, reform participants, and others knowledgeable about the 
specifics of the reform process.

We did not evaluate the effect of reforms on beneficiaries or on 
program effectiveness. Consideration of any entitlement reform process 
should not be taken to imply approval of the specifics of any given 
reform. We limited our review to documents available in English. (For 
more information on our scope and methodology, see app. I.) We 
conducted this work in accordance with generally accepted government 
auditing standards from July 2007 through January 2008.

Background:

In all countries, entitlement programs such as public pension programs 
and disability programs are politically sensitive and difficult to 
change. The hard choices needed to change the path of these programs 
include trade-offs that are likely to result in redistribution, 
creating "winners" and "losers." Such choices raise issues of fairness 
and access, embodying varying views about the appropriate roles of 
government and individuals in society. Reform may entail short-term 
sacrifice for long-term gain. Some experts have expressed the view that 
entitlement reform in the United States faces unique challenges due to 
the existence of multiple program constituencies combined with a 
complex legislative process with many hurdles to enactment.

Since the early 1990s, several commissions have been established to 
develop entitlement reform proposals, and considerable public debate, 
especially on Social Security reform, has taken place. (See app. II for 
more information on historical U.S. commissions on entitlement reform.) 
Both the current President and his predecessor discussed the need for 
Social Security reform and participated in related town meetings on 
Social Security, raising public awareness of the need for change. We 
have developed criteria to help Congress evaluate Social Security 
reform proposals.[Footnote 6] These criteria reflect the multiple and 
conflicting goals that will have to be balanced in any reform package. 
To date, major structural change to the entitlement programs that drive 
the long-term fiscal challenge has not been enacted.

With regard to both Social Security and Medicare, consensus on the need 
for reform and reform approaches remains elusive. For example, some do 
not believe fundamental structural change to Social Security is 
necessary. Among those who have developed proposals, some include 
individual accounts and others do not. No major changes have been 
enacted to Social Security since 1983, when reform legislation based on 
a proposal developed by the Greenspan Commission was enacted in 
response to a near-term crisis in program financing. In contrast, 
Medicare has been modified frequently, but the most significant change 
was a 2003 expansion of benefits to include prescription drugs. This 
step served to significantly increase the fiscal imbalance in the 
Medicare program.

Challenges posed by the growth path of entitlement spending are not 
unique to the U.S. Other developed countries have faced and continue to 
face the challenges of unsustainable social welfare programs including 
public pensions and health care. Moreover, many developed countries, 
especially in Western Europe, face more daunting demographic shifts due 
to population aging than the U.S. Figure 1 shows changes in the elderly 
dependency ratio-the number of older people relative to those of 
working age. As figure 1 shows, population aging in France, Germany, 
Italy, Japan, Sweden, and the United Kingdom is already as advanced 
today as is projected for the U.S. in 2020.

Figure 1: Elderly Dependency Ratio for Selected High-Income Countries, 
1980 to 2020:

[See PDF for image] 

This figure is a multiple vertical bar graph illustrating the elderly 
dependency ratio for selected high-income countries, 1980 to 2020. The 
vertical axis of the graph represents number of elderly per 100 persons 
of working age. The horizontal axis of the graph represents eleven 
countries. The following data is depicted, with numbers approximated: 

Country: Australia; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 15; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 19; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 38. 

Country: Canada; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 15; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 18; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 38. 

Country: France; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 21; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 23; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 32. 

Country: Germany; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 22; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 22; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 34. 

Country: Italy; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 20; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 25; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 35. 

Country: Japan; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 11; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 23; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 46. 

Country: Netherlands; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 17; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 20; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 32. 

Country: New Zealand; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 16; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 17; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 25. 

Country: Sweden; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 25; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 27; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 33. 

Country: United Kingdom; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 23; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 24; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 31. 

Country: United States; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 1980: 16; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2000: 17; 
Number of elderly per 100 persons of working age, 2020 (projected): 24. 

Source: United Nations, World Population Prospects: The 2006 Revision, 
and World Urbanization Prospects: The 2005 Revision. 

Note: The number of individuals over age 59 for each 100 persons of 
working age, defined as age 15 to 59.

[End of figure]

Spending on public pensions has presented major challenges in many 
countries where such spending generally represents a larger share of 
the total economy than in the U.S. Figure 2 shows this spending as a 
share of gross domestic product (GDP) in selected high-income countries 
in 1990 and 2003.

Figure 2: Public Spending on Old-Age and Survivors' Pensions in 
Selected High-Income Countries, 1990 and 2003:

[See PDF for image] 

This figure is a multiple vertical bar graph illustrating the public 
spending on old-age and survivors' pensions in selected high-income 
countries, 1990 and 2003. The vertical axis of the graph represents 
percent of GDP from 0 to 16. The horizontal axis of the graph 
represents eleven countries. The following data is depicted, with 
numbers approximated: 

Country: Australia; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 3.5; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 4. 

Country: Canada; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 4.1; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 4.2. 

Country: France; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 10.8; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 12.2. 

Country: Germany; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 10.4; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 12.0. 

Country: Italy; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 10.4; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 14.0. 

Country: Japan; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 5.0; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 9.0. 

Country: Netherlands; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 7.2; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 6.4. 

Country: New Zealand; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 7.8; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 4.5. 

Country: Sweden; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 9.2; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 10.4. 

Country: United Kingdom; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 5.5; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 6.0. 

Country: United States; 
Percent of GDP, 1990: 6.0; 
Percent of GDP, 2003: 6.1. 

Source: OECD Social Expenditures Database, as shown in Pensions at a 
Glance: Public Policies across OECD Countries, 2007 Edition. 

[End of figure] 

As in the U.S., health care cost growth presents challenges in OECD 
countries, with total healthcare spending, both public and private, 
generally rising as a share of GDP in the last 10 years.[Footnote 7] 
Although total health care spending in other countries is smaller as a 
share of the economy than in the United States, a larger share of that 
spending is public. On average, the public share of health spending in 
OECD countries was 73 percent in 2005.[Footnote 8] For example, in 2005 
public health spending as a share of GDP in Germany was 8.2 percent, or 
77 percent of total health spending; in France 8.9 percent, or 80 
percent of total health spending; and in the U.K. 7.2 percent, or 87 
percent of total health spending. In the U.S., public health spending 
was 6.9 percent of GDP, or 45 percent of total health spending in 
2005.[Footnote 9] Figure 3 shows public and private health spending in 
2005 for selected countries.

Figure 3: Spending on Health Care as a Percent of GDP for Selected High-
Income Countries in 2005:

[See PDF for image] 

This figure is a stacked vertical bar graph illustrating the spending 
on health care as a percent of GDP for selected high-income countries 
in 2005. The vertical axis of the graph represents percent of GDP from 
0 to 16. The horizontal axis of the graph represents ten countries. The 
following data is depicted: 

Country: Australia; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 3.1; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 6.4; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 9.5. 

Country: Canada; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 2.9; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 6.9; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 9.8. 

Country: France; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 2.2; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 8.9; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 11.1. 

Country: Germany; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 2.5; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 8.2; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 10.7. 

Country: Italy; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 2.1; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 6.8; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 8.9. 

Country: Japan; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 1.5; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 6.6; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 8.1; 

Country: New Zealand; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 2.0; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 6.9; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 7.9. 

Country: Sweden; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 1.4; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 7.7; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 9.1. 

Country: United Kingdom; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 1.1; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 7.2; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 8.3. 

Country: United States; 
Private spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 8.4; 
Public spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 6.9; 
Total spending on health care as a percentage of GDP: 15.3. 

Source: OECD Health Data 2007 database. 

Notes:

Public expenditures include those incurred by public funds including 
state, regional and local government bodies and social security 
insurances. Private expenditures include out-of-pocket payments, 
payments by private insurances, charities and for occupational health 
care. For more information on OECD's methodology, see [hyperlink, 
http://www.ecosante.org/OCDEENG/411000.html]:

The relative shares of public and private spending do not reflect 
government tax subsidies for private health care spending. In the 
United States, federal revenue losses due to health care-related tax 
preferences amounted to more than 1.5 percent of U.S. GDP in 2005. As a 
result, for the U.S., the private share is somewhat overstated and the 
public support understated. Health tax preferences also exist in some 
other countries, but information about these preferences is not readily 
available.

Data for Australia and Japan are from 2004. The United Kingdom uses a 
different methodology to collect their data. Data are not available for 
the Netherlands after 2002. 

[End of figure] 

Health care cost containment is expected to continue to pose challenges 
in other countries as well as in the U.S. Projections developed by the 
Commission of the European Communities show that the management and 
control of health care spending will be a critical part of overall 
efforts in European Union (EU) countries to ensure progress towards 
more sustainable public finances. This is also true outside the EU. For 
example, in our recent study of accrual budgeting,[Footnote 10] we 
found that Australia projects that health care spending will nearly 
double as a share of GDP by 2046-2047. Similarly, the United Kingdom 
projects that its health spending will increase from around 7 ½ percent 
of GDP in 2005-2006 to around 10 percent of GDP by 2055-2056. New 
Zealand projects a rise in the ratio of health spending to GDP of 6.6 
percentage points between 2005 and 2050 resulting in health spending of 
about 12 percent of GDP.

Results in Brief:

Since the 1980s, many OECD countries have enacted reforms to 
politically sensitive and popular entitlement programs such as public 
pensions, disability, unemployment, welfare (social assistance), and 
health care programs. Since the early 1990s, almost all of the 30 OECD 
countries have restructured their pension programs, with a clear trend 
toward reduced benefits. Disability benefit reform has also been widely 
undertaken, with changes made to reduce costs and achieve better 
integration of the disabled into society. Between 1985 and 2000, 14 
OECD countries reduced disability benefits, with the Netherlands 
undertaking one of the largest reductions as well as policy changes to 
promote integration of the disabled. Reforms to unemployment programs, 
with an emphasis on cost containment, took place in several countries 
in the early 1990s. As in the U.S., growth in spending for public 
health programs in many counties continues to be a major concern 
despite efforts to constrain it. In some countries entitlement reform 
efforts addressed multiple programs simultaneously.

Several kinds of pressures have been cited as prompting entitlement 
reform efforts. Many reform efforts began or accelerated in an 
environment of economic and fiscal crisis. In the early 1990s, for 
example, the Swedish pension reform process took on urgency as Sweden 
experienced its worst recession since the 1930s. Long-term concerns 
about population aging and economic competitiveness in an age of 
globalization also have prompted reforms. Supranational factors, such 
as a desire to meet the fiscal criteria required for entry into the 
European Monetary Union, have also been cited as motivating reform.

Reform is difficult. Commissions can help, but they are a tool in a 
larger process, not a guarantee of reform success.

* Before reform can be enacted and implemented, policymakers and the 
public generally need a shared understanding of the size, scope, and 
nature of the problem. This understanding can emerge from the work of a 
commission, as it did in Sweden's pension reform; or from political 
leaders who define and communicate a problem, as in the Netherlands' 
disability reform.

* In the three case study reform efforts we reviewed, once reform was 
on the agenda proposals were developed by commissions-usually small- 
established by governments with a strong commitment to reform. Although 
composition and charters varied, leadership was important in these 
commissions. Standing commissions can also have a role in reform by 
coordinating stakeholders or by monitoring and providing consultations. 
Whether ad hoc or standing, commissions or other groups can take 
divisive and controversial issues out of the usual political process, 
facilitate the consultation and negotiation necessary for coalition 
building, and help insulate policymakers from political risks. Reform 
has also been undertaken without major efforts to build coalitions and 
reach consensus, but to a lesser extent.

* In the reforms we examined, the process did not proceed in a simple 
or straightforward manner. Reform processes were generally complex and 
often conflict-ridden before they ultimately succeeded in enacting 
legislation.

* Each country's reform process was unique, but some re-adjustment or 
fine-tuning often occurred over time. In some cases, unexpected 
challenges emerged as reforms were implemented that required 
adjustments including due to unintended consequences. In other changes 
new rounds of reform were enacted as the reform process became 
iterative.

* Given that there is uncertainty about the future, some reforms 
foresee that re-adjustment will be necessary and put in mechanisms to 
do this. Although assuming and structuring an iterative reform process 
may be politically necessary, this can undermine public trust in a 
program. Automatic mechanisms (or triggers) have been included in some 
recent pension reforms including those in Sweden and Germany. These 
mechanisms require benefit adjustments without policy changes under 
specified demographic or economic conditions.

Many Countries Have Reformed Entitlement Programs and Reform Efforts 
Continue:

Since the 1980s, many OECD countries have enacted reforms to 
politically sensitive and popular entitlement programs such as public 
pensions, disability, unemployment, social welfare (social assistance) 
programs, and health care. Like the U.S., many other developed 
countries have experienced and expect to continue to experience a rate 
of cost growth in their public health programs that exceeds the growth 
rates of their economies. Unlike the United States, however, many other 
countries have made major changes to their public pension programs in 
the last two decades. (For a summary of selected reform efforts, see 
app. III.)

In the 1980s, some countries sought to address future financial 
shortfalls in their public pension programs by increasing 
contributions, but since the early 1990s many pension reform efforts 
have sought to reduce future public finance commitments. As shown in 
figure 2, spending on public pensions in some other developed countries 
is much larger than in the United States. Contribution rates are also 
higher. In the U.S., contribution rates for Social Security are 12.4 
percent of taxable income. In Sweden and Germany, rates in 2006 were 
over 18 percent; in the Netherlands over 25 percent; and in Italy over 
30 percent.[Footnote 11] Governments have either undertaken far- 
reaching, structural pension reforms or adopted a series of smaller 
reforms which, taken together, affect future pension entitlements 
substantially. Although Sweden undertook a single major overhaul; more 
typically, several rounds of reform took place as in Italy, France, 
Germany, and Japan.

Since the early 1990s almost all the 30 OECD countries have made 
changes to restructure their public pension programs with a clear trend 
toward reduced benefit promises.[Footnote 12] In 16 OECD countries that 
implemented significant reform in the last 10 years, OECD estimates 
that the benefit promise was reduced by 22 percent.[Footnote 13] Italy, 
Sweden, France, Austria, Germany, and Japan reduced replacement rates 
for workers with average earnings by at least 6 percent.[Footnote 14] 
In assessing future fiscal risk of individual European Union member 
countries, a 2007 European Commission report cited pension reforms in 
Italy, Sweden, France, Austria, Denmark, and Germany as having 
contributed to increased sustainability of public finances.[Footnote 15]

Efforts to reform pensions are continuing. For example, in France the 
current government is seeking changes including reductions to pension 
benefits for certain civil servants; reform of civil service pensions 
was previously attempted in 1995.[Footnote 16] The U.K., which 
restructured its public pension program in the 1980s and has made 
numerous changes since then, has recently enacted a new major reform 
following the work of the Turner Commission.[Footnote 17] Among other 
changes, this reform combines an increase in the retirement age with 
higher promised benefits to address an emerging problem of poverty 
among the elderly. This tension between reducing costs and the need to 
avoid increasing the number of elderly poor is reflected in the OECD's 
2007 report on the status of pension reforms. This report noted that in 
some countries further reforms are needed to ensure fiscal 
sustainability while in others previous enacted reforms may have to be 
revisited given the risk of old-age poverty for low-income workers.

Non-pension social welfare programs have also been subject to change, 
with many reforms reducing benefits.[Footnote 18] For example, in 14 of 
20 OECD countries changes in disability policy between 1985 and 2000 
included reductions in compensation, with the Netherlands undertaking 
the largest reductions.[Footnote 19] The Netherlands also undertook the 
largest policy change with respect to increased integration of disabled 
people. More recent disability reforms in the Netherlands were cited as 
contributing to curbing long-term public spending in the European 
Commission's 2006 report assessing the sustainability of public 
finances.[Footnote 20] Since the early 1990s, concerns about cost 
containment have played a role in reforms of unemployment programs in 
countries such as Canada, France (2001), and Germany (2003-2005). 
[Footnote 21] Reforms of social assistance (welfare) programs were 
enacted in the Netherlands (2004). Efforts to reform other types of 
programs continue as well. For example, Sweden is seeking further 
reform of its sickness benefit, under which general tax revenue and 
employer and employee contributions pay employees for sick 
days.[Footnote 22]

In some countries, reforms sought to make changes to related programs 
at the same time. For example, the Hartz reforms in Germany integrated 
unemployment and social assistance. In recent years the Netherlands has 
undertaken reform of unemployment, social assistance, and health care 
as well as disability. In Denmark a 2006 comprehensive reform package 
known as the "Welfare Agreement" included changes to unemployment 
policy, increases in the retirement age, and provisions for increased 
investment in education. The Danish government described the Welfare 
Agreement as part of a national reform strategy building on two decades 
of reforms and was based in part on the work of a 2003 expert 
commission.[Footnote 23]

In our 2003 report on strategies to increase labor force participation 
among older workers, we studied policies in three countries with high 
levels of older worker participation and recent reforms-Japan, Sweden, 
and the United Kingdom. All three countries had made changes to their 
pension systems. Sweden and the United Kingdom had also tightened 
eligibility requirements for disability insurance to reduce its use as 
a path to early retirement. Officials in these countries agreed on the 
need for comprehensive reforms, e.g., changes to national pension 
reforms should be accompanied by reforms in the employer-provided 
pension system, in related social insurance programs such as 
disability, and in labor market policies.[Footnote 24]

OECD countries have made many reforms to their health care systems 
since the 1980s, and reform efforts continue.[Footnote 25] For example, 
the Netherlands has recently restructured its health system with a 
stated aim of containing health care cost increases.[Footnote 26] We 
found no country that has been able to optimize the multiple goals of 
cost containment, access, and quality over time. As has been noted by 
the Deputy Head of OECD's Health Division, the challenge for OECD 
countries today is how to ensure their health systems will be 
sustainable given population aging and a rate of health care cost 
growth faster than the economy.

As in the United States, structural reform of health systems is highly 
controversial, and the reform process may take time. The 2002 Rurup 
Commission in Germany was charged with developing recommendations to 
ensure sustainability for the social insurance system including 
pensions, health care, and long-term care. Two opposing approaches for 
health care financing were discussed, but the Commission was unable to 
reach consensus on a proposal.[Footnote 27] Reform of the Netherlands 
health care system in 2006 incorporated some elements similar to 
recommendations made by a commission that concluded its work almost 20 
years earlier.

A Variety of Pressures Have Led to Entitlement Reform in Other 
Countries:

Several kinds of pressures-economic and fiscal crisis, the demographic 
changes of population aging-have been cited as prompting entitlement 
reform efforts. In many countries reforms occurred in environments of 
economic and fiscal crisis. Long-term concerns about population aging 
and economic competitiveness are commonly cited as prompting reforms, 
especially of pension programs. Supranational factors such as a desire 
to meet the fiscal criteria needed for entry into the European Monetary 
Union have also been cited as constituting pressures for reform.

Many reform efforts began or accelerated in an environment of economic 
and fiscal crisis.[Footnote 28] In the early 1990s, for example, the 
Swedish pension reform process took on urgency as Sweden was 
experiencing its worst recession since the 1930s, with growing public 
debt and a devaluation of its currency. A Parliamentary Working Group 
established by the government in 1991 developed the reform proposal 
that was ultimately enacted in 1998. Similarly, the 2002 reform effort 
of the German pension system was triggered by an economic downturn that 
worsened the program's financial condition and led to the establishment 
of the Rurup Commission. Although the Commission reached no consensus 
on health care and long-term care, the pension reforms it recommended 
were enacted in 2004 and 2007.[Footnote 29] According to experts, 
pension reforms in Australia, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Italy, and New 
Zealand all took place in an environment of economic and fiscal crisis.

Long-term pressures are also frequently cited as motivating reforms. 
Our 2005 report found that demographic as well as fiscal factors 
necessitated pension reform in many countries.[Footnote 30] With rising 
longevity and declining birthrates, the number of workers for each 
retiree is falling in most developed countries, straining the finances 
of national pension programs, particularly where contributions from 
current workers fund payments to current beneficiaries. Population 
aging affects pension programs and projections directly. Swedish and 
German government officials attributed pension reforms primarily to 
concerns about the programs' long-term fiscal sustainability. 
Similarly, according to a Japanese government official, since 1994, 
projections of Japan's pension program's financial condition have 
necessitated a series of reforms largely due to further aging of 
society.[Footnote 31]

Concerns about competitiveness in an era of globalization combined with 
current and future population aging are also cited as leading to 
entitlement reforms and influencing reform options.[Footnote 32] In the 
1980s some pension reforms raised payroll tax contribution rates, but 
in the 1990s a desire in some countries to keep non-wage labor costs as 
low as possible tilted options toward benefit reductions. For example, 
in Germany, avoiding higher payroll tax contribution rates was one 
concern in their 1990s reforms. Reforms that included benefit 
reductions and eligibility changes in pension and non-pension social 
welfare programs, e.g., disability and unemployment, sought to increase 
labor force participation rates as one response to competitiveness 
concerns. The European Commission has noted a need to increase 
employment rates, notably of older workers, as an issue of prime 
importance in EU countries. The Commission has further noted that in 
countries where a significant decrease in the benefit ratio, i.e., 
average pensions over GDP per worker, is projected, raising employment 
rates of older workers is especially important as this could reduce the 
risk of possibly inadequate pensions in the future.

Supranational factors are also said to have played a part in bringing 
about entitlement reforms. In some European countries, the desire of 
some countries to meet fiscal criteria for entry into the European 
Monetary Union (EMU)[Footnote 33] has been cited as a factor leading to 
reforms. For example, Italy's 1992 pension reform was undertaken as the 
country sought to join the EMU. Entitlement reforms during the 1990s in 
countries such as Netherlands, France, and Germany have similarly 
linked to these countries' efforts to meet the fiscal criteria for EMU 
membership. More recently, the European Commission has encouraged its 
member countries to adapt their public programs including entitlements 
such as pensions and health care to be better able to cope with future 
economic challenges as part of the "Lisbon Strategy" to ensure growth 
and jobs.[Footnote 34] Denmark's first progress report on its national 
reform program, developed as a contribution to the Lisbon Strategy, 
focuses on its 2006 Welfare Agreement.

Clearly, these various pressures are not mutually exclusive in Europe 
or elsewhere. For example, according to a Japanese government official, 
the 1985 pension reform in Japan was introduced as part of a broader 
fiscal reform in a context of the end of rapid economic growth, growing 
public debt, and the aging of society. Neither are the pressures 
sufficient explanations for why some countries enacted reform changes 
to increase program sustainability while others did not.[Footnote 35] 
As a result, according to OECD, some countries' pension systems 
continue to need a major overhaul.

How Reform Proposals Were Developed in Other Countries:

Detailed reform proposals in other countries were generally developed 
by commissions or other specially established groups.[Footnote 36] 
Proposal development, however, is only one stage in what is often a 
long, difficult, and conflict-ridden process.[Footnote 37] Before 
reform can be enacted and implemented, policymakers and the public 
generally need to have a shared understanding of the size, scope, and 
nature of the problem. Next, reform options need to be developed, and 
reform packages that key stakeholders can support need to be 
negotiated. This stage generally involves dialogue, negotiation, and 
coalition building to reach a sufficient degree of consensus across 
political parties and groups in society. Special groups outside the 
normal political process such as commissions can be used to create a 
space where the difficult negotiations needed to reach consensus can 
take place. Such groups can mitigate political risk for reform 
participants as well as educate the public, creating pressure for 
change. Finally, a reform package needs to be enacted and implemented 
in succeeding years. Whatever the reform process, leadership is key at 
all stages for reform to be enacted and sustained. As one expert has 
put it,[Footnote 38] for broad-ranging reform to occur, two conditions 
must exist: first, the public must believe that change is needed, and 
second, leadership must be able to transform this perception into an 
agenda that crystallizes the issues and points to their solution.

Stage 1 of Reform: Framing the Problem:

In reform efforts we examined, various events and actions helped define 
the size and scope of the problem. In Sweden a commission helped to put 
pension reform on the agenda. A large and diverse commission worked 
from 1984 to 1990 without being able to reach consensus on a proposal, 
but its analyses are credited with having laid the groundwork for later 
reform, raising public awareness of the problem and leading 
policymakers to conclude that major structural change was needed. (For 
more information on the Swedish pension reform, see app. IV.)

It has been noted that the timing of reform depends on political 
leadership-in the first instance leadership to make clear that there is 
a crisis. In the Netherlands' long and difficult disability reform 
process, actions by political leaders defined the problem and 
communicated its urgency. (For more information on the Netherlands' 
disability reform, see app. V.)

* The Netherlands disability reform: the "1 million" measure. In the 
early 1990s, government efforts to reform the disability program in the 
Netherlands and reduce benefits had met with considerable political 
opposition. Then-Prime Minister Lubbers made a speech in which he 
declared that if the number of disability claimants exceeded 1 million, 
he would resign. Analysts, including some who participated in later 
reform efforts, cited this measure as having re-framed the public 
discussion about disability. Although this number was never reached, 
the "1 million" number became a widely accepted symbol of the need for 
reform in both expert studies and public discussion. This continued to 
be the case as the number of disability claimants rose and fell 
throughout the 1990s and into the early 2000s.[Footnote 39]

* Netherlands disability reform: televised hearings by the Buurmeijer 
Parliamentary Commission led to a change in the conversation about 
disability. In the mid 1990s, the Buurmeijer Commission, a special 
parliamentary inquiry chaired by Social Democrat Flip Buurmeijer, 
investigated the administration[Footnote 40] of disability by employers 
and employee groups. According to experts, this kind of parliamentary 
inquiry is rare and considered significant in Dutch politics.[Footnote 
41] The work of the Commission took many months and received widespread 
public attention through nightly televised hearings. According to 
experts, this Commission's work had profound effects on the subsequent 
reform process. The Commission's recommendations influenced later 
legislation; in the public discussion they raised issues as to whether 
the program was meeting its goal of serving the truly needy. 
Ultimately, the reform process in the Netherlands became a conversation 
about the appropriate roles and responsibilities of government, 
employers, and employees in society.

* In Germany Chancellor Schroeder developed a reform agenda he termed 
"Agenda 2010" that was aimed at modernizing the German social insurance 
system and labor market. The Schroeder government established numerous 
commissions as part of this effort, including the Hartz Commission on 
unemployment program reform and the Rurup Commission on the sustainable 
financing of the social insurance system. (For more information on the 
German pension reform, see app. VI.)

Stage 2: Proposal Development:

In the three case study reform efforts we reviewed, once reform was on 
the agenda, proposals were developed by commissions established by 
governments with a strong commitment to reform. Commissions served as a 
venue for negotiation and compromise leading to a reform package. 
Commissions that developed proposals were generally small, but their 
composition varied, as did their charters. Within the commissions, 
leadership was also important. Negotiated behind closed doors, reform 
packages were presented publicly prior to legislative enactment and 
sometimes changed following participation in the reform process by 
other stakeholders. According to OECD, most countries set up ad-hoc 
commissions when pension reform processes are being launched.

* Swedish 1991 Parliamentary Working Group.[Footnote 42] In Sweden, a 
small parliamentary working group developed the reform package. This 
group was chaired by a minister of the center-right government then in 
power, who had participated in the earlier commission. The group's 
small size and limitation to political leaders were unusual, as was the 
exclusion of representatives from employer groups and labor unions. The 
major parties were represented. In contrast to the earlier 1984 
commission, which had been tasked with making program changes within 
the existing framework, the 1991 group had a broad charter for reform. 
Between 1991 and 1994, the group negotiated the outlines of a major 
structural pension reform, keeping deliberations within the 
group.[Footnote 43] This outline became the basis of legislation 
enacted in 1998.

* The 2001 Donner Commission. In the Netherlands, the Donner Commission 
crafted a disability reform package that included a recommendation for 
major structural change. Established by a Minister following many 
reform changes in the 1990s, the Commission was composed of respected 
public figures from major parties who were able to negotiate for those 
parties. Members were not currently active in national politics and not 
identified with the disability issue. The commission developed a reform 
proposal in meetings closed to the public and made use of an expert 
staff. Observers attribute the enactment of reform to the leadership of 
both the Minister who established the commission and guided its 
proposal through the legislative process and the Commission chair, Piet 
Donner.

* The 2002 Rurup Commission. This German commission was chartered with 
developing proposals to make the public pension system, the health care 
system, and the long-term care social insurance sustainable. The 
Commission was established by the Social Democratic government of 
Chancellor Gerhard Schroeder as a means to garner support for reform 
from both within his party and outside.[Footnote 44] The Commission was 
large (26 members), but broke into smaller sub-groups to address the 
three programs. While it was unable to reach consensus on health care 
and long-term care, the commission did make recommendations for pension 
reform. Led by experts, the pension sub-group worked closely with the 
Commission chair, Bert Rurup, an academic identified with the Social 
Democratic Party then in power. The Commission's recommendation for a 
"sustainability factor" in the pension system was enacted in 2004 by 
the Social Democrats; its recommendation to raise the retirement age 
was enacted in 2007 by a coalition of Christian Democrats and Social 
Democrats.

In some reforms, the process of negotiation and proposal development 
continued after the commission had concluded its work. For example, the 
Donner Commission's disability reform proposal was reviewed by an 
institution representing employer groups, labor unions, and the 
government. This review, a routine feature in the Dutch legislative 
process, led to further changes before legislation was 
enacted.[Footnote 45] Similarly, according to the Danish government, 
the 2006 Welfare Agreement was based not only on the recommendations of 
the Danish Welfare Commission but also on the work of two other groups, 
the Danish Globalisation Council and a tripartite council of employer, 
employee (e.g., labor unions), and government representatives.

Although all three case study countries used ad hoc commissions, 
commissions involved in a reform process can also be standing 
institutions. Japan used Pension Councils coordinated by a government 
ministry and composed of representatives of employers' groups, labor 
unions, academic researchers, and government officials to facilitate 
pension reforms during the 1990s.[Footnote 46] Other countries also 
have standing commissions.[Footnote 47] Whether ad hoc or standing, 
commissions or other specially established groups are commonly used to 
develop reform specifics because they can take divisive and 
controversial issues out of the usual political process, facilitate 
consultation and negotiation, and help to insulate policymakers from 
political risks inherent in supporting a reform package.

Although commissions are a frequently used means to develop proposals, 
governments have also taken other approaches. In some countries the 
government developed reforms on a unilateral basis, i.e., without 
seeking consensus through participation by opposition parties or other 
stakeholders. Sometimes such efforts succeeded in creating changes; in 
other cases, they did not. The 1980s pension reform in the U.K. was 
enacted despite opposition and sustained over time with numerous 
adjustments.[Footnote 48] However in France a unilateral approach did 
not lead to legislative enactment. A 1995 civil service pension reform 
effort met with sufficient opposition that it was not enacted. The same 
thing happened with a 1994 pension reform effort in Italy, which led to 
a change in government.[Footnote 49] In other cases, the public was 
involved in the reform process. Canada's 1997 pension reform included 
public consultations that highlighted consensus principles for reform. 
In Japan's 2000 reform, reform alternatives were presented to the 
public in the early stages of discussion. Indeed, a 2000 study noted 
that a process involving consultation, negotiation, and public 
education has been used for pension reform in highly industrialized 
countries in recent years.[Footnote 50]

The Process of Reform Is Complex and Not Sequential:

In reforms we examined, the reform process as it unfolded did not 
proceed in a simple or straightforward manner from problem definition 
to negotiation and consensus-building to enactment. Rather, the reform 
process at some points seemed more like a zigzag or "two steps forward, 
one step back" than a straight line.

* An important provision of the 1997/1999 pension reform by the 
Christian Democrats in Germany was revoked by the successor Social 
Democratic government. This same government subsequently undertook a 
structural reform in 2001 and in 2002 established the Rurup Commission 
to address unexpected shortfalls in pension financing.

* In Sweden, following the work of the 1991 group, a second 
Parliamentary Working Group worked out legislative details of the 
reform between 1994 and 1998 while leaders of the Social Democratic 
party worked to persuade opponents within their party on the need for 
and contours of reform.

Similarly, the activities of consultation, negotiation, and public 
education may occur at several points in the process, with commissions 
performing multiple roles. For example, the Danish Welfare Commission 
both developed recommendations used in the legislative process and 
educated the public about the need for change. The 2002 Rurup 
Commission's recommendation to raise the retirement age is said to have 
led to a controversial public debate, with this change enacted in 2007.

Reform is difficult. Commissions can help, but they are a tool in a 
larger process, not a guarantee of reform success. For reform changes 
to be enacted and sustained, a sufficient degree of consensus across 
the major parties and acceptance by the general public of the need for 
change must be achieved. Leadership is needed to bring this about. In 
Sweden and Germany, formal and informal cross-party cooperation was key 
in moving reform forward; in the Netherlands, disability reforms were 
enacted by various coalition governments. Consultation took place with 
key stakeholders either formally or informally.[Footnote 51] As experts 
have noted, the tension is to build a broad coalition to assure the 
permanency of the reform, while preserving the main policy initiatives 
sought in the reform process.[Footnote 52]

The Reform Process May Continue Following Enactment of Legislation:

Each country's reform process was unique, but some re-adjustment or 
fine-tuning often occurred over time. In some cases adjustments were 
needed to address emerging implementation challenges. In other cases 
change included new rounds of reform as the reform process became 
iterative. In recent pension reforms, a trend has emerged toward 
including automatic mechanisms, or triggers, which aim at insulating 
reforms from policy change. These types of mechanisms are structured to 
reduce benefits without legislative action under specified 
circumstances, e.g., if demographic or economic trends prove 
unexpectedly unfavorable.

As reforms are implemented, unexpected challenges may emerge that call 
for fine-tuning or other adjustments including due to unintended 
consequences.

* In Sweden, following the implementation of pension reform, changes to 
individual account administration have been under discussion. Since 
account inception, the number of Swedes making active investment 
choices has dropped, with more people routing their money into the 
government default option. A government committee has recommended 
limiting investment options from over 700 accounts to around 200, and 
converting the default fund into a fund that adjusts based on an 
individual's age. To date, no changes have been enacted.

* In the Netherlands, one of the disability reforms sought to provide 
employers with incentives to limit the number of their employees 
claiming disability. However, some experts said that in response 
employers began to seek ways to identify prospective employees who 
posed a risk of becoming sick or disabled. Legislation was then passed 
preventing health screenings in the hiring process.

* The United Kingdom experienced substantial difficulties in the 1980s 
when it implemented its pension reform, in part, by providing too 
little public education and relying on its already existing regulatory 
system, which proved to be inadequate. In what has become known as the 
'mis-selling' controversy, high-pressure sales tactics were used to 
persuade individuals, especially older workers, to take up individual 
accounts when they would more likely have been better off retaining 
their occupation-based pensions.

As we noted in our report on other countries' pension reforms,[Footnote 
53] the extent to which new provisions are implemented, administered, 
and explained to the public may affect the outcome of the reform.

In some cases the need to revisit is anticipated and initial 
legislation provides for some form of periodic re-visiting under 
specified circumstances. For example, Germany and Japan established 
"soft" triggers as part of their pension reforms. The 2001 German 
reform included a requirement that if projections did not meet 
specified thresholds for maximum expected contribution rates or minimum 
replacement rates in the future, government action would need to be 
taken. Triggered in 2002, this mechanism led to the establishment of 
the Rurup Commission. A similar mechanism in Japan requiring an 
examination every 5 years of its pension program's sustainability led 
to additional rounds of reform.[Footnote 54] Other countries also have 
established institutions to monitor pension fiscal sustainability and 
in some cases are tasked with recommending adjustments as appropriate.

Reform processes can be described as one-time "big bang" reforms as in 
Sweden; more commonly, reforms are iterative as in the Netherlands 
disability reform or German pension reform. In our work on other 
countries' pension reforms, we noted that, in almost every country we 
studied, debate continued about alternatives for additional reform 
measures even after initial changes were enacted. It is clearly not a 
process that ends with one reform, and it often requires more than one 
type of reform. An iterative process can be understood as reflecting 
the difficulties posed by reform of popular and politically sensitive 
programs.

Some have pointed out that frequent changes may have a downside. Some 
officials we spoke with noted that although an iterative process may be 
politically necessary, constant re-opening of issues is not ideal. In 
some cases where several rounds of reforms occurred, frequent changes 
to pension systems created public mistrust. For example, in Japan 
noncompliance with the system became an issue in the public debate in 
the early 2000s following a series of pension reforms driven by rapid 
population aging. Swedish officials said that achieving a consensus on 
a reform that would be politically sustainable was one reason that the 
reform process took so long.

Because reform is so difficult, a major goal is to have a reform that 
will last. Given that there is uncertainty about the future, some 
pension reforms include mechanisms to reduce benefits (and in some 
cases also increase revenues) without intervention by policymakers. In 
2001 as part of its reform changes Sweden enacted an automatic 
balancing mechanism to adjust benefits if other reform changes prove 
insufficient to keep the pension program in fiscal balance.[Footnote 
55] The automatic balance mechanism is a kind of "hard trigger" that 
comes into play under specified circumstances.[Footnote 56] Following 
Sweden's lead, several other countries have adopted similar types of 
mechanisms, and these mechanisms are considered an emerging trend in 
pension reform.[Footnote 57] Germany's 2004 pension reform included a 
"sustainability factor" as recommended by the Rurup Commission. The 
sustainability factor automatically adjusts benefits based on the 
number of workers to beneficiaries. Pension reforms in Japan, 
Italy,[Footnote 58] Canada and other countries have also included 
automatic adjustment mechanisms. An aim of this type of mechanism is to 
insulate reforms from future legislative changes, thereby increasing 
trust in program sustainability and compliance with the system. In 
addition, experts have noted that such mechanisms could mitigate 
political risk for policymakers in the event reductions are triggered.

The effects of such mechanisms generally remain to be seen.[Footnote 
59] In Japan, a mechanism adopted in 2004 to limit increases in 
contribution rates has been triggered. According to one expert, the 
result has been accepted by the public following a painful public 
debate.

Experts have expressed differing views concerning these types of 
mechanisms as used in pension reforms. Some have expressed the view 
that automatic mechanisms may be the best approach to slowing cost 
growth in the entitlement programs driving the long-term fiscal 
challenge. Others have noted that mechanisms could be subject to 
erosion should they be triggered and the required benefit reductions 
prove politically unacceptable.[Footnote 60] Those who support the 
concept of automatic mechanisms note that in this event legislators 
always have the option of suspending the mechanism and are unlikely to 
raise benefits above the levels that would have been the case had the 
mechanism never been activated. In any case, triggers may make it more 
difficult to ignore that a problem exists.[Footnote 61]

Implications for the United States:

The experiences of other countries suggest that while reform is 
difficult, it is also possible. Countries more advanced in population 
aging and facing greater demographic challenges than ours have 
undertaken reforms of major entitlement programs. In many countries, 
reform occurred despite political processes that made it difficult. 
Consensus had to be built in coalition governments, and leaders had to 
work across parties to achieve a broad consensus for reform. 
Nonetheless, politically sensitive and popular programs such as public 
pensions were reformed including those which were (and are) more 
generous to individuals and constituted a larger share of their economy 
than is the case in the U.S.

The experiences of other countries also underline that for reform to be 
enacted and sustained, it needs broad-based support that reaches across 
parties and groups. In the U.S. this means that reform will need to be 
done on a broad bipartisan basis. For reform to be sustained, a broad 
public consensus must be reached on the need for reform.

Other countries' reform processes show that at all points in the 
process leadership will be needed to create and sustain consensus. In 
other countries leaders undertook many actions to begin the reform 
process and move it forward to enactment and implementation. Leaders 
framed the problem in new ways, persuaded the public and other 
policymakers that reform was necessary and urgent, established 
commissions to develop reform packages, and worked to build coalitions 
to support reform. Throughout the process, leaders had to negotiate 
tensions between the need to build broad coalitions while maintaining 
reform goals. In the U.S., presidential leadership will be key if 
reform is to happen.

As in the 1983 reform of Social Security, other countries' experiences 
show that commissions can be a useful tool. Commissions in other 
countries moved reform forward by educating the public and also 
provided a forum for developing reform packages. Commissions we studied 
often met out of the public eye, thereby facilitating discussions and 
negotiations that could then be supported by all those involved. 
Establishing a commission, however, does not guarantee that a reform 
package that can gain consensus will be developed. While commissions 
can help, they are not a substitute for leadership or political will.

Other countries' experiences show that for reform to occur, certain 
elements must fall into place. For reform to occur and be sustained, 
the public and policymakers in other countries were ultimately 
persuaded that reform was necessary and urgent. Coalitions were built 
to support reform, and a package that could gain support and a broad 
consensus was negotiated and enacted. For reforms to be enacted and be 
sustained by future governments, the involvement of major stakeholders 
whose support was necessary for the success of the reform was needed, 
whether through membership in the commission or through some other 
means. How this happened differed from country to country-each 
country's process was unique. Taken as a whole, reform processes were 
generally complex and often conflict-ridden before they ultimately 
succeeded in enacting legislation.

One conclusion is that it is hard to know-before legislation is 
actually enacted-how close any given process is to reaching its 
culmination. In the U.S., past commissions and other public discussions 
on entitlement reform have laid groundwork for reform even while 
appearing to "fail," e.g., no reform was enacted. For Social Security 
reform in this country, options have been developed, and policymakers 
have had the opportunity to learn from past initiatives that did not 
gain consensus. Public debate has been ongoing for some time, with 
considerable and growing public awareness that Social Security and 
Medicare are unsustainable. While no one can know what needs to happen 
next, given leadership committed to reform, it is possible that our 
reform process could be further along than it may seem.

We are sending copies of this report to interested parties. Copies will 
also be made available to others upon request. In addition, the report 
will be available at no charge on the GAO Web site at [hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov]. This report was done under the direction of Susan 
J. Irving, Director of Federal Budget Analysis, Strategic Issues, who 
may be reached at (202) 512-9142 if you have any questions about this 
report. Contact points for our Offices of Congressional Relations or 
Public Affairs may be found on the last page of this report. GAO staff 
who made major contributions to this report are listed on appendix VII.

Signed by: 

David M. Walker: 
Comptroller General of the United States: 

[End of section] 

Appendix I: Scope and Methodology:

To develop criteria for "major entitlement reforms" and to select case 
studies and reform efforts for further review, we conducted a 
literature review and consulted with experts.

We reviewed GAO reports on other countries' entitlement reforms for 
pension programs, labor market reforms, and disability reforms; OECD 
reports on pension reforms, disability reforms, and long-term care 
reforms; the WHO Health Care in Transition country profiles; 
International Monetary Fund country profiles and studies of health care 
reforms by the International Network Health Policy & Reform, which 
monitors health policy trends and developments in 20 industrialized 
countries. We reviewed materials from a 2007 OECD conference of budget 
officials from several OECD countries involved in budgeting for 
entitlement programs and concerned about the future cost implications 
of these programs.

* We reviewed papers from a 2006 conference on entitlement reforms and 
reform process in European countries including reforms to pensions, 
unemployment, and health care programs.

* We analyzed OECD information on pension reforms to identify countries 
that had made the largest reductions in benefit promises. We reviewed 
the 2005/06 and 2007 sustainability assessments made by the European 
Commission of EU for the sustainability of public finances in those 
countries, focusing on countries where risk assessments indicated that 
entitlement reforms had improved sustainability.

* We consulted with the staff responsible for the GAO reports on 
international entitlement reform and with OECD officials responsible 
for pension reform and health care. We also consulted with an OECD 
official who had convened a conference on budgeting for entitlement 
reforms and with an academic expert on budgeting and public policy.

Although OECD countries have made many reforms to their health care 
systems since the 1980s, and reform efforts continue, we found no 
country that has been able to optimize the multiple goals of cost 
containment, access, and quality over time. Some countries have already 
undertaken national pension reform efforts to address demographic 
changes similar to those occurring in the United States, and in a 
previously issued report we drew lessons from their experiences.

Based on these reviews and consultations we narrowed our focus to 
highly developed, relatively affluent OECD countries on the grounds 
that these countries were more likely to have similar types of 
political pressures to the U.S., but even more daunting long-term 
challenges and demographic changes. We further limited our review to 
reforms enacted within the last 10 years that had aimed at slowing cost 
growth and increasing fiscal sustainability. Finally, we selected the 
following reform efforts for further review: pension reform in Sweden, 
Germany, Japan, Italy, France, U.K., and Canada; disability reform in 
the Netherlands; and reform of social programs in Denmark.

To understand how reform proposals were developed and to understand the 
dynamics of entitlement reform, we reviewed political science 
literature on reform process in various countries including theoretical 
studies of the stages of reform. We also reviewed studies from experts 
including researchers at the Center for Strategic & International 
Studies (CSIS), the Urban Institute, the International Labour Office 
(ILO), and the Center for Retirement Research.

To analyze how reform proposals were developed and to supplement our 
analysis of the other objectives, we selected three reform efforts for 
more in-depth review. In selecting reform efforts we took into account 
information from the literature review and recommendations by the 
experts we consulted. We selected reform efforts representing a range 
of approaches to reform process including whether any mechanisms for 
revisiting changes or triggers were built into the reform. Each of the 
reform efforts selected had included one or more commissions or other 
specially established groups.

* Sweden's pension reform was an example of a major reform that has 
been sustained without further structural change following a long 
process.

* Germany's pension reform was an example of an iterative process over 
an extended period of time and also an example of a process that 
included a trigger requiring actions under specified circumstances in 
its reforms.

* The Netherlands' disability reform was an example of an iterative 
process of reform of a non-pension program and as an example of 
entitlement reform in a country that has undertaken reform of multiple 
entitlements in recent years.

In these countries we interviewed government officials knowledgeable 
about the reform process, at least one commission participant or 
commission staffer, and independent experts.

We did not evaluate the effect of reforms on beneficiaries or on 
program effectiveness. Consideration of any entitlement reform process 
should not be taken to imply approval of the specifics of any given 
reform. We limited our review to documents available in English.

[End of section]

Appendix II: Summary of Selected U.S. Commissions:

Greenspan Social Security 1983: 
Statutory basis? No; Executive order but agreement by the Congress; 
Imminent crisis or other action-forcing event? Yes; 
Presidential leadership and commitment to success of effort? Yes; 
Within the general charter was scope broad or restricted (and how)? 
Broad; 
Number of commissioners; (No. of current elected federal officials/No. 
of others): 15 (7/8); 4 Senators, 3 House Representatives, 8 non-
elected (included 2 former Members of Congress; also insurance, labor, 
business representatives); 
Appointments by both President and Congress? Yes; 5 by President, 5 by 
Senate, and 5 by House; 
Bipartisan? Yes; 
Co-chairs? No; 
Open/transparent process including public hearings? Yes; but found way 
to do smaller conversations; 
Commission resulted in report? (month, year issued): Yes; (Jan. 1983); 
Report set forth specific, actionable recommendations? Yes; 
Under establishment of Commission was action required by the President 
or Congress? Or were there other action-forcing provisions? No; 
Did President/Congress take required action or some other responsive 
action? Yes; 
Other relevant information: [Empty]. 

Kerrey-Danforth Bipartisan Commission on Entitlement and Tax Reform 
1994: 
Statutory basis? No; Executive order; 
Imminent crisis or other action-forcing event? No; 
Presidential leadership and commitment to success of effort? 
Within the general charter was scope broad or restricted (and how)? 
Broad; entitlement spending and tax reform; 
Number of commissioners; (No. of current elected federal officials/No. 
of others): 32 (22/10); 
Appointments by both President and Congress? No; presidential 
appointments only; 
Bipartisan? Yes; of the 22 Members of Congress, 11 Democrats and 11 
Republicans; 
Co-chairs? Yes, functionally; technically Chair and Vice-Chair; 
Open/transparent process including public hearings? Yes; all meetings 
and hearings were televised on C-SPAN. All commission documents, 
transcripts and reports made public on a CD; 
Commission resulted in report? (month, year issued): Yes; failed to 
reach consensus on specific recommendations; (Jan. 1995); 
Report set forth specific, actionable recommendations? No; but 
recommended 5 broad principles for crafting "solutions to our fiscal 
problems"; 
Under establishment of Commission was action required by the President 
or Congress? Or were there other action-forcing provisions? No; 
Did President/Congress take required action or some other responsive 
action? No; 
Other relevant information: Interim report widely respected; source for 
much of what is said today. 

Breaux-Thomas Commission on the Future of Medicare 1998: 
Statutory basis? Yes; Balanced Budget Act 1997; 
Imminent crisis or other action-forcing event? No; 
Presidential leadership and commitment to success of effort? No; 
President strongly disagreed with proposed recommendations; 
Within the general charter was scope broad or restricted (and how)? 
Broad; 
Number of commissioners; (No. of current elected federal officials/No. 
of others): 17 (9/8); 
Appointments by both President and Congress? Yes; 1 of 17 (Chair) by 
both President and Congress; 4 others by President; others by 
congressional leadership (Republicans appointed 4 each house and 
Democrats 2 each house) = 8 by each party; 
Bipartisan? Yes; 
Co-chairs? Yes, functionally; technically Breaux = Chair; Thomas = 
"Administrative Chair"; 
Open/transparent process including public hearings? Yes; 
Commission resulted in report? (month, year issued): No; proposed 
recommendations failed to gain required 11 votes; 
Report set forth specific, actionable recommendations? N/A; 
Under establishment of Commission was action required by the President 
or Congress? Or were there other action-forcing provisions? No; 
Did President/Congress take required action or some other responsive 
action? N/A; 
Other relevant information: Outlook for Medicare appeared to improve 
while Commission met. 

Bush Committee to Strengthen Social Security 2001: 
Statutory basis? No; Executive order; 
Imminent crisis or other action-forcing event? No; 
Presidential leadership and commitment to success of effort? Yes; 
Within the general charter was scope broad or restricted (and how)? 
Restricted; had to include individual accounts; 
Number of commissioners; (No. of current elected federal officials/No. 
of others): 16 (0/16); Included 3 former Members of Congress; 
Appointments by both President and Congress? No; presidential 
appointments only; 
Bipartisan? Yes; 8 Republicans and 8 Democrats; 
Co-chairs? Yes; 
Open/transparent process including public hearings? Yes; 
Commission resulted in report? (month, year issued): Yes; (Dec. 2001); 
Report set forth specific, actionable recommendations? Report set forth 
3 reform models; 
Under establishment of Commission was action required by the President 
or Congress? Or were there other action-forcing provisions? No; 
Did President/Congress take required action or some other responsive 
action? No; 
Other relevant information: Limit on scope and conditions for 
membership perceived as having negative impact on acceptance of 
analyses-even those not related to specific individual account issue; 
Democrats appointed not viewed as representative of party point of 
view. 

9/11 Commission 2002: 
Statutory basis? Yes; Pub. L. No.107-306; 
Imminent crisis or other action-forcing event? Yes; 
Presidential leadership and commitment to success of effort? Partial; 
Within the general charter was scope broad or restricted (and how)? 
Broad; 
Number of commissioners; (No. of current elected federal officials/No. 
of others): 10 (0/10); 
Appointments by both President and Congress? Yes; 1 by President 
(Chair); 1 by Senate Minority Leader with House Minority Leader consult 
(Vice-Chair); 2 each by Senate Majority Leader and House Speaker; 2 
each by Senate and House Minority Leaders; 
Bipartisan? Yes; 
Co-chairs? Yes, functionally; technically Chair and Vice-Chair; 
Open/transparent process including public hearings? Yes; 
Commission resulted in report? (month, year issued): Yes; (July 2004); 
Report set forth specific, actionable recommendations? Yes; 
Under establishment of Commission was action required by the President 
or Congress? Or were there other action-forcing provisions? No; 
recommended actions to both but not required; 
Did President/Congress take required action or some other responsive 
action? Yes - many were enacted; 
Other relevant information: [Empty]. 

Mack-Breaux Tax Reform 2005: 
Statutory basis? No; Executive order; 
Imminent crisis or other action-forcing event? No. 
Presidential leadership and commitment to success of effort? No; 
Within the general charter was scope broad or restricted (and how)? 
Restricted; required revenue neutrality and keeping incentives for 
homeownership and charitable giving, and encouraging savings; required 
to consider equity and simplicity too; 
Number of commissioners; (No. of current elected federal officials/No. 
of others): 9 (0/9); Chair and Vice-Chair were former Senators; 1 
former House Representative on panel; also included 4 professors and 2 
"tax practitioners"; 
Appointments by both President and Congress? No; presidential 
appointments only.
Bipartisan? Yes; 
Co-chairs? Yes; 
Open/transparent process including public hearings? Yes; 
Commission resulted in report? (month, year issued): Yes; (Nov. 2005); 
Report set forth specific, actionable recommendations? Yes; 
Under establishment of Commission was action required by the President 
or Congress? Or were there other action-forcing provisions? No; 
recommended actions to President but not required; 
Did President/Congress take required action or some other responsive 
action? No; 
Other relevant information: Commission viewed report as starting point 
for congressional consideration of tax reform; no action yet.

Source: GAO analysis. 

[End of table] 

[End of section] 

Appendix III: Summary of Selected Reform Efforts: 

Most recent reform: 
Sweden: Pension reform: Passed in 1994, details passed in 1998; 
implemented in 1999; automatic stabilizer in 2001; 
Japan: Pension reform: 2004; 
Germany: Pension reform: 2004; Retirement age: 2007; 
Netherlands: Disability reform: 2005; 
Canada: Pension reform: 1998; 
United Kingdom: Pension reform: 2007; 
Italy: Pension reform: 2004; 
France: Pension reform: 2003. 

Pressure(s) for reform: 
Sweden: Aging population; predictions that the system was unsustainable 
in the mid-1980s; a recession in the early 1990s; 
Japan: Population aging; statutory requirements for periodic 
monitoring; 
Germany: Population aging; high non-wage labor costs; economic 
downturn; 
Netherlands: High number of beneficiaries; population aging; 
Canada: Primarily financial pressures: 
* declining economic conditions; 
* declining demographic conditions; 
* increase in disability benefit use; 
* benefit increases from the 1970s; also, in 1993, pension assets were 
not enough to pay benefits (benefits funded by collecting provinces' 
debt to pension plan); 
United Kingdom: Growing levels of pensioner poverty; 
Italy: Population aging; economic crisis in early 1990s; meeting 
Maastricht criteria for entry into European Monetary Union; 
France: Deficit in the pension system and unfavorable projections for 
the future solvency of the system. 

Reform history: 
Sweden: Process that led to reform began in 1984; 
Japan: Beginning in 1985, pensions have been reformed multiple times 
due to population aging and lower economic growth rates with the goal 
of achieving fiscal sustainability; 
Germany: Incremental reforms began to be implemented in 1992 under the 
Kohl government; 
Netherlands: Many reforms and changes to the system since the 1980s; 
Canada: Pension reform in Canada is difficult, and thus uncommon, 
because it requires consent from the provinces; 
United Kingdom: Pension system changes had been common in the UK and 
have been seen as unilaterally driven by government in power; recent 
reform included public outreach; 
Italy: Reform efforts began in 1992 and continued through the decade. 
These efforts were met with controversy, including strikes and 
protests; 
France: Reform of public pensions in 1993 stemmed from discussions in 
the mid-1980s. Attempt at reform of civil service pensions in 1995 was 
met with strikes and ultimately failed. 2003 reform is seen as the 
beginning of a series of reforms. 

Commission(s) or other institutional prompts: 
Sweden: Swedish government appointed a commission to study pension 
system in 1984, which met through 1990; a parliamentary working group 
met from 1991 to 1994 to create legislation; another parliamentary 
group focusing on implementation details met from 1994 to 1998; 
Japan: National Pension Council: a standing government commission; 
Germany: German government appointed a commission in 2002 following an 
economic downturn and financial crisis in the public pension system- 
and a 2001 law required the government to take action when projections 
were unfavorable; 
Netherlands: Parliamentary committee investigated disability 
administration in 1993 leading to greater public awareness; the 
government appointed a commission in 2000; its recommendations were 
deliberated by a standing body with representatives from government, 
employers, and employee groups; reform passed in 2005; 
Canada: No commission or special group was used. Reform was based upon 
negotiations with Ministry of Finance and provincial ministers along 
with information collected from town hall meetings; 
United Kingdom: An independent government commission; 
Italy: Italy has a standing commission to monitor expenditures. This 
commission is not seen as having prompted 2004 reform; 
France: Pension Advisory Council was created in 2000. This is a 
standing body. 

Composition of commission/special group(s): 
Sweden: 1984 commission included experts, political party 
representatives, unions, business organizations, and government 
officials. The 1991 group had 8 members representing the parties in 
power; 6 of them were Parliament Members. The 1994 group had 8 members 
from the parties that agreed to the reform; 4 were current Parliament 
Members, 1 was a former Member; 
Japan: Government assessment begins with pension experts from Ministry 
of Health and Welfare. They consult with National Pension Council 
(which includes business groups, trade unions, and pension experts) 
along with political parties; 
Germany: Pension reform was handled by a subset of 26-member 
commission; this commission included academic experts, officials from 
lower levels of government, employer and union representatives; 

Parameters of commission/study group: 
Sweden: 1984 commission was tasked with examining the challenges of the 
old system, and making recommendations within the old system's 
framework. The 1991 group was tasked with creating legislative 
proposals for a system that is fiscally and politically sustainable in 
the long term; 
Japan: Standing commission required to provide input to Ministry of 
Health and Welfare's assessment of financial outlook every 5 years and 
assist in developing reforms if necessary;
Germany: The Rurup Commission was tasked to make recommendations on 
ways to achieve sustainability in the pension system, within the 
parameters established in 2001-payroll tax at no more than 20% up to 
2020 and no more than 22% to 2030; replacement at no less than 67% of 
average net earnings; 
Netherlands: 1993 committee: Members of Parliament from multiple 
parties; 2000 commission: Five representatives of large political 
parties (not from parliament), one independent expert, and one civil 
servant; 
Canada: N/A; 
United Kingdom: Three members and a small secretariat. One member from 
private sector, one from unions, one academic expert; 
Italy: Not applicable for this reform; 
France: Includes representation from government, labor, business, and 
elderly interest groups. 
Netherlands: Goal of recent reform was to decrease share of population 
receiving disability-to increase size of labor force; 
Canada: N/A; 
United Kingdom: Commission charged with looking at level of pensions, 
level of pension savings, level of other savings among pensioners, and 
to make recommendations based upon these findings; commission produced 
three reports; 
Italy: Not applicable for this reform; 
France: Purpose of council is to monitor French retirement and put 
forth recommendations based upon negotiations with involved partners. 

Source: GAO. 

[End of table] 

[End of section] 

Appendix IV: Pension Reform in Sweden: 

[End of section] 

Reform Overview: Significance of the Reform: 

Sweden's pension reform, a complete overhaul enacted in 1998, 
restructured a pension system that was the hallmark of the Swedish 
social welfare system and a result of political conflict in the 1950s. 
The reform's novelty is evident in its employment of a notional defined 
contribution approach to the pay-as-you-go benefit component and an 
automatic balance mechanism.[Footnote 62] In addition to the 
substantive reform, the process that facilitated the changes is also 
noteworthy, namely the lengthy period of deliberations that ultimately 
reconciled disparate interests and gathered strong support in 
Parliament. 

As a result of the reforms, Sweden's pension system changed from a 
traditional pay-as-you-go defined benefit plan, like the U.S. Social 
Security program, to a system where participants' benefits are more 
closely related to their contributions.[Footnote 63] Like its 
predecessor, the new system uses pay-as-you-go financing; however, the 
former benefit scheme was replaced with notional and individual 
accounts whose balances are based primarily on work-related 
contributions, and a guaranteed minimum pension for low-income 
individuals (see table 1).[Footnote 64] Credits for child care, 
education, military service, and sickness also contribute to an 
individual's pension rights. The system relies on a reserve fund for 
financing during periods of economic or demographic changes that cause 
increased pension liabilities.[Footnote 65] If liabilities exceed the 
reserve fund, a balancing mechanism will temporarily adjust indexation 
of benefits and interest rates on the notional accounts, thus 
preventing contribution rate increases. 

Table 1: Sweden's Public Pension System, Pre-and Post-Reform: 

Benefits and Structure: 
Pre-reform: 
* Flat rate universal benefit, established in 1913; 
* Earnings-related benefit, established in 1960. Payouts calculated 
based on an individual's 15 highest earning years. Supplements were 
available for low-income individuals; 
Current system: 
* Notional accounts æ payouts that are based on credits from payroll 
contributions and credits from eligible nonwork periods; 
* Mandatory individual accounts; 
* Guaranteed minimum benefit for low-income individuals. 

Financing: 
Pre-reform: 
* Approximately 19 percent payroll tax on employers; 
* General tax revenue supported the universal benefit; 
Current system: 
* Employers and employees pay equally into an 18.5 percent tax on 
earnings; 16 percent goes to notional accounts, and 2.5 percent goes to 
individual accounts; 
* General tax revenue supports the guaranteed minimum benefit and 
nonwork credits for notional accounts. 

Source: GAO analysis. 

Note: Employees only pay on earnings up to the pension ceiling, while 
employers pay on all earnings. 

[End of table] 

Origins of Reform: 

By the mid-1980s, the actuarial predictions showed that the old system 
was financially unsustainable. Accordingly, Swedes were losing faith in 
the system. Demographic changes, increased longevity and an aging 
population soon eligible for benefits, threatened to strain the system. 
In 1980, 21.9 percent of Swedes were age 60 or older, compared with 
15.6 percent in the U.S. 

Other considerations also played a role in reform. The benefit formula 
had an "inequitable and unsystematic relationship" between benefits and 
contributions according to one government official, implying that 
decreased work did not necessarily mean reduced benefits. Furthermore, 
the income ceiling for benefits was indexed to consumer prices, meaning 
that as more people earned wages above the ceiling, the earnings- 
related benefit would eventually become a flat rate. 

Even before the reform effort of the 1990s, the contributory pension 
system had been a focus for political conflict. The system, which was 
enacted by a Social Democrat Parliament in 1960, was only gradually 
accepted by non-Socialist parties.[Footnote 66] After an oil crisis in 
1979, the non-Socialist Parliament unilaterally attempted to remove 
energy prices from the pension benefit indexation formula. The effort 
failed and the Social Democrats campaigned on the issue and regained 
control of Parliament in 1982. Once in power, the Social Democrats 
changed the index formula but did not initiate other reforms, causing 
non-Socialists to believe the Social Democrats abandoned their reform 
intentions. 

The Reform Process: 

In 1984 the Social Democratic government appointed a pension committee 
tasked with examining the challenges of the system, and proposing 
reforms within the existing framework.[Footnote 67] The committee's 
membership was typical of a Swedish Parliamentary commission: it was 
large and included representatives from political parties, unions, 
employers, experts, and government. The committee's deliberations 
lasted six years, culminating in a report that proposed changes to 
survivors' pensions, but not an overall reform (see fig. 4). According 
to one expert, the report said the financial problems would not peak 
until about 2010-2015 and therefore reform was not an immediate need. 

By the early 1990s, Sweden experienced its most serious recession since 
the 1930s, marked by an increased deficit, high unemployment, near 
failure of several major banks, and a devaluation of the currency. 
Starting in 1990, Sweden's budget surplus became a deficit, leading to 
a dramatic escalation in government debt. The recession served as the 
final spur for pension reform, making the issue a high priority in 1991 
for the newly elected center-right coalition in Parliament, who 
appointed a working group on pensions. 

This group was tasked with producing proposals for a new pension system 
that would be financially solvent and broadly supported. Unlike the 
1984 committee, the working group was small, consisting of two Social 
Democrats and a representative from each of the six other parties in 
Parliament at the time; everyone but the chairman and one of the 
working group members were Members of Parliament.[Footnote 68] The 
small size of the group was the result of a decision by the chairman, 
who also wrote the group's directives. The chairman was the Minister of 
Social Affairs at the time, and a former member of the 1984 committee. 
According to a government official, it is unusual for a minister to 
chair a working group, but it showed the importance of the reform. The 
exclusion of interest groups such as labor unions was justified by the 
work of the 1984 committee, who laid the reform's foundation by 
highlighting financial problems, leaving reform negotiations to the 
politicians, according to an expert. Despite their lack of direct 
participation, interest groups had close ties to the parties and 
participated in occasional meetings of special groups known as 
reference groups. 

Prior to negotiating specific compromises, the working group came to an 
agreement on broad principles, according to a group member. To prevent 
the endless introduction of new debates, members agreed to reach 
consensus before they consulted with nonmembers. An expert and a 
working group member described the members as "social engineers" who 
possessed the leadership, knowledge, and personal dynamics necessary to 
produce legislation. During negotiations, both the majority coalition 
and the Social Democrat opposition adjusted their preferred reform 
models in exchange for preservation of their overall goals. For 
example, the Social Democrats agreed to incorporate individual accounts 
into the systemæan inclusion important to conservativesæbut Social 
Democrats advanced their views by insisting that the accounts be kept 
to a relatively small portion, 2.5 percent, of benefits. The strength 
of the Social Democrats as the opposition party permitted 
responsibility for legislative outcomes to be diffused between both the 
majority and the opposition, according to an academic expert; each 
party could cite the other as the force necessitating unpopular 
concessions. The deliberations resulted in a consensus and a proposal 
outlining principles for reform. 

A majority of Parliament æfive parties representing about 85 percent of 
the electorateæpassed the principles in 1994 just prior to an election. 
However, the legislation did not contain specific legal provisions and 
therefore only served as a guide for future legislation. Due to the 
relatively early agreement on the reform principles and small size of 
the group, the opportunity for interest groups and politicians to 
muster strong opposition or support was limited, according to a working 
group member. Reform debates were not public, a condition that prompted 
some criticism of the process. 

To formulate the details of the reform, a second working group, 
composed of representatives from the five parties who supported the 
reform, convened later that year following the return of the Social 
Democrats to a majority in Parliament.[Footnote 69] As with the 1991 
working group, there was little public discussion of the 1994 group's 
deliberations. During this period, however, Social Democrat leaders 
faced opposition to the reforms within their party, as some members 
believed the reforms veered too far from the existing system the Social 
Democrats created. Party officials had to persuade members to support 
the reforms, holding lengthy discussions. Additionally, it took time to 
work with the Ministry of Finance, which did not have a direct role in 
the proposal's formation. During these negotiations, Sweden's National 
Insurance Boardæthe government agency responsible for administering 
pensions at the timeæbegan preparing for implementing the reforms. In 
June 1998, Parliament passed the finalized legislation. One group 
member told us that it was significant that the bulk of the reform was 
accomplished all at once. Unlike incremental reforms, one set of 
changes helps to reduce the public's uncertainty and ensure the trust 
and security that is vital for social insurance schemes, according to 
one expert. To introduce the reforms to the public, the government 
launched a three year information campaign, which included media 
outreach and mailings of individual benefit projections. Payments under 
the new system began with retirees born after 1937, who receive 
benefits from both the old and new systems.[Footnote 70] 

Post-Reform Implementation and Adjustments: 

Although the bulk of the reform was enacted in 1998, the government 
faced challenges with implementation and ensuring the political 
insulation and fiscal stability of the system. Because the new system 
is still influenced by demographics, it was necessary to introduce an 
automatic balancing mechanism to assure the system's stability, a part 
of the system discussed in the 1990s, but not enacted until technical 
details were resolved in legislation passed in 2001. The mechanism was 
intended to help protect the system from political recalibration during 
system imbalances by automatically activating when necessary and 
therefore minimizing intervention from Parliament. 

The Swedish government also sought to refine the administration of 
individual accounts. A committee was established in 2004 to evaluate 
program guidance, clarity of investment options, system costs, and the 
possibility of including life annuities in addition to the unit-linked 
funds already being offered. The committee report showed that the 
number of Swedes making active investment choices has dropped since the 
accounts' inception, with more people routing their money into the 
default option offered by the government. In addition to proposing 
steps to reduce administrative costs, the committee recommended 
limiting investment options from over 700 accounts to around 200, and 
converting the default fund into a fund that adjusts based on an 
individual's age. To date, the government has not implemented any 
changes.[Footnote 71] 

Legacy of the Reform: 

The reforms enacted in Sweden highlight the importance of coupling 
universally acknowledged problem definitions with knowledgeable 
leadership in order to pass reform. Specifically, the analysis 
performed by the 1984 pension committee, a large group with broad 
membership, set the stage for the legislative negotiations in the 
1990s, according to an expert. Economic conditions and eroded 
confidence in the old pension system helped activate those 
deliberations in the 1990s. The 1991 working group, which had the 
necessary social engineering skills and knowledge, used the projections 
of program fiscal unsustainability to craft a major structural reform 
that was agreeable to a strong majority of Parliament. Although also a 
criticism, the autonomy of the 1991 working group and its small size 
decreased the potential opportunities for derailing the legislation and 
helped build consensus across party lines, according to one expert. 

The result of the two decade and multi tier process was a complete 
reconstruction of the pension system, designed with the aim of 
insulating it from the temptation of constant political fine-tuning. As 
the reforms are gradually phased in, the Swedish public's true grasp 
and support of the changes remains to be seen. Government survey data 
from the early 2000s suggests the public's understanding of the reform 
is not high, despite outreach efforts.[Footnote 72] Although some 
criticism exists of the reform, officials and experts believe it has 
public support and will be sustained. Another government official 
stated that people who currently oppose the system tend to base their 
opinions on politics and not because of lost benefits. One result of 
the reform, according to a government official and member of the 
working group, is that young Swedes who previously had no confidence in 
the system now believe they will receive a small pension. The complete 
impact of the reforms and any potential need for reexamination will be 
more evident as the phase-in of the system is more complete and baby 
boomers begin collecting benefits. 

Figure 4: Key Events in Sweden's Pension Reform, 1982 through 2001: 

[See PDF for image] 

This figure is a time-line of key events in Sweden's pension reform, 
1982 through 2001. The following data is depicted: 

Political events: 
1982: Social Democrats control Parliament; 
1984–1990: Pension committee; 
1991: Non-Socialist Coalition controls Parliament; 
1991–1994: Pension working group; 
1994: Social Democrats control Parliament; 
1994–1998: Pension implementation group. 

Legislative events: 
1992: Reform sketch released; 
1994: Initial reform legislation passed; 
1998: Final details of the reform passed; 
2001: Automatic balancing mechanism passed. 

Source: GAO analysis. 

[End of figure] 

[End of section] 

Appendix V: Disability Reform in the Netherlands: 

Reform Overview: Significance of the Reform: 

Since 1967, the disability program in the Netherlands has had a broad 
definition of "disability" that included partial disability benefits. 
This broad definition opened the disability system to high levels of 
use. For most of the 1980s, 1990s and the first half of this decade, 
the proportion of the labor force on long-term disability was over 10 
percent. Because there was broad support for the program and disabled 
individuals in general, reforming the disability system was politically 
difficult. The disability program had been a source of national pride 
for the Netherlands, referred to as the "crown jewel" of its social 
programs. After multiple attempts at reforming the system, a structural 
reform of the program was implemented in 2006 that is seen as 
significant by government officials and experts. The process leading to 
the reform was long and difficult, requiring many attempts at reform 
and a shift in public perception of the disability program. Figure 5 
illustrates the key events that occurred in this reform process. 

Figure 5: Key Events in the Netherlands Disability Reform Process: 

[See PDF for image] 

This figure is a time-line of key events in the Netherlands Disability 
Reform Process. 

Political Events: 
1982: Christian Democrat Ruud Lubbers becomes Prime Minister, leading a 
generally center right coalition; 
1990: Prime Minister Lubbers claims that if the number of disability 
beneficiaries reaches one million, he will resign; 
1991: Further disability benefit cuts proposed, leading to protests; 
1993: Buurmeijer Commission holds parliamentary inquiry; 
1994: Labor Party member Wim Kok becomes Prime Minister with moderate 
coalition government; 
2000: Donner Commission established; released report in 2001; 
2002: SER responds to Donner Commission recommendations; 
2002: Christian Democrat Jan Peter Balkenede becomes Prime Minister, 
leading a generally center right coalition. 

Legislative Events: 
1982–1987: Series of disability benefit cuts, including: 
* 1982–1983: Abolition of disability tax exemption; 
* 1984: Reduced earnings base; 
* 1985 Reduced replacement rate; 
* 1987: Reduction in partial disability benefit; 
1992–2002: Reforms that stressed labor reintegration for disabled 
individuals, including: 
* 1992: TAV Act (repealed in 1995); 
* 1993: TBA Act; 
* 1994: TZ Act; 
* 1996: WULBZ Act; 
* 1998: PEMBA Act; 
* 2002: Gatekeeper Act; 
2005: Parliament passes disability reform that was implemented in 2006. 

Source: GAO analysis. 

[End of figure] 

Disability in the Netherlands Differs from that in the United States: 

The Netherlands disability system differs significantly from disability 
programs in the United States and other countries. The disability 
program in the Netherlands differs from Disability Insurance (DI) in 
the United States in the following ways: 

* The Netherlands provides a "partial disability" benefit. 
Individuals in the Netherlands can claim a benefit if one is 
"partially" disabled, meaning that those who can still work and those 
who are still working can receive benefits if working at a reduced 
capacity.[Footnote 73] Partial disability is rated on a percentage 
basis; before 2006, beneficiaries had to be at least 15 percent 
disabled to receive the benefit. No partial disability benefit exists 
in the United States. In the United States, for a person to receive DI 
benefits, the impairment must be of such severity that not only is the 
person unable to do previous work but, considering his or her age, 
education, and work experience, is unable to do any other kind of 
substantial work that exists in the national economy. 

* There is virtually no waiting period for receiving benefits in the 
Netherlands. 
While a claimant in the Netherlands does not qualify for the disability 
program at first, he or she immediately qualifies for benefits under 
employer financed "sickness insurance" for up to 2 years. In the United 
States, one must have or expect to have a disabling condition for at 
least 1 year and there is a mandated 5 month waiting period before 
receiving benefits. 

* The disability program was originally administered by employer and 
labor groups in the Netherlands until the mid-1990s. 
In contrast, U.S. disability benefits are administered by the 
government. 

Figure 6 shows the number of disability beneficiaries for each year 
since the beginning of the disability program. Over this time, the 
number of beneficiaries has generally increased. In the 1990s after a 
period of decreasing beneficiaries, the number once again went up. 

Figure 6: Disability Beneficiaries in the Netherlands: 1968 through 
2007: 

[See PDF for image] 

This figure is a line graph illustrating the disability beneficiaries 
in the Netherlands, 1968 through 2007. The vertical axis of the graph 
represents number of beneficiaries in thousands from 0 to 1,000. The 
horizontal axis of the graph represents years from 1968 through 2007. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the Netherlands Ministry of Social 
Affairs and Employment. 

[End of figure] 

Origins and History of Reform: 

Number of those receiving disability increased in the 1980s and 
remained high despite benefit reductions: 

Following a recession in the late 1970s, the Netherlands had an 
increased rate of unemployment. Individuals-if they qualified- started 
to claim disability benefits instead of unemployment benefits because 
disability provided a more desirable benefit. For some, the benefit 
facilitated early retirement. As the economy improved, however, 
similarly high levels of disability beneficiaries continued. The 
government believed that this was too costly and, if similar levels of 
disability receipt continued, costs would continue to rise. 

Reform of the disability system began in the 1980s and early efforts 
focused on reducing disability benefits to reduce costs. These reforms 
included ending tax exemptions for the disabled, a 10 percent reduction 
in the disability benefit's replacement rate, and a decrease in the 
earnings base (which is used to calculate disability benefits). While 
the amount paid for individual benefits decreased, government data show 
that the number of beneficiaries increased in this decade. 

Policy reform in 1990s focused on return-to-work measures as public 
perceptions of the program changed: 

The number of people on disability continued to be high during the 
1990s, with studies showing that the disability system was used as an 
option for early retirement and unemployment ("stress" was also cited 
as a reason for receiving disability benefits). Concerns about the 
effect of population aging also created pressure for change, as this 
could lead to even more use of the disability program. 

A change in policy reform from benefit reductions to return-to-work 
provisions was accompanied by political events that helped to change 
public perception of the disability system and made the public more 
amenable to reform. 

In 1990, Prime Minister Ruud Lubbers (a Christian Democrat who served 
as Prime Minister from 1982 through 1994) stated that the Netherlands 
was "sick" and threatened to resign if the number of those in the 
disability program in the Netherlands reached 1 million. Experts agreed 
that 1 million was an arbitrary number, but it became an accepted 
measure of the need for reform. While this threshold was never 
surpassed, his statement generated public interest and concern over the 
disability program, and the "1 million" measure continued to shape 
discussion of the program past Prime Minister Lubbers' tenure. 
Throughout the 1990s and beyond, experts noted that whenever the number 
on disability approached 1 million, public discussion of the disability 
system increased. 

In 1991, major retrenchments of the disability program were proposed by 
the governing coalition, a combination of the center-right Christian 
Democratic party and the center-left Social Democratic party. These 
proposals were met with disfavor, leading to large protests. According 
to experts, the governing coalition was threatened with a loss of power 
and did not follow through with the proposed reforms. One expert said 
that this series of events was the catalyst for a shift in focus on the 
part of the government to reforming the administration of the 
disability system instead of a further reduction in benefits. 

In 1993, a special parliamentary commission known as the Buurmeijer 
Commission had an impact on public perceptions of the disability 
program. The Buurmeijer Commission was a parliamentary group that held 
hearings on social insurance programs[Footnote 74] including the 
disability program. The chair was Flip Buurmeijer, a Social Democratic 
member of Parliament. The commission led to policy recommendations, but 
experts say that its most important legacy was informing the public and 
changing its perception of the disability system. The hearings exposed 
fraud and abuse in the disability program and showed the public how 
both employer and employee interests benefited from misuse of the 
disability benefit. One expert said that the commission identified this 
moral hazard, which convinced the public that change was needed. 

The commission had several features that experts said gave it the power 
to change public opinion. First, parliamentary commissions are a rarity 
in Dutch government, used primarily to investigate scandals and thus 
significant attention was paid to the disability hearings. Second, the 
hearings were broadcast on national television and viewed by many, 
creating public awareness of fraud in the disability system. 

Following the Buurmeijer Commission, reforms were implemented to 
address the disability system's problems. Several laws were passed in 
the 1990s containing provisions that aimed at returning disabled 
employees to the labor force. Examples of these included: laws 
mandating that employers pay the employee for an initial period of 
time;[Footnote 75] incentives for employers to retain and recruit 
disabled workers; and requiring reintegration plans for disabled 
individuals to be submitted to a government organization. 

However, experts said in most cases, reforms resulted in only limited 
effects on new disability cases. Some of the laws during this period 
had unintended consequences. One example given by an expert is a law 
that intended to provide incentives to employers to limit the number of 
employees that claimed disability while employed with them. As a 
result, employers began to screen potential employees and, according to 
experts, would not hire those who posed a risk of becoming sick or 
disabled. In response, the government enacted a law that prevented 
employers from performing health screenings for new employees. Other 
disability reforms that proved controversial or problematic were 
repealed. Some laws did have more lasting effects, including a 1998 
PEMBA law, which indexed employers' contributions to the disability 
system based on their risk.[Footnote 76] 

Structural Reform Implemented in 2006, Prompted by the Donner 
Commission: 

In 2000, the Minister of Social Affairs and the Minister of Interior 
Affairs of the moderate governing coalition established a commission 
chaired by Piet Hein Donner, a member of the Council of State.[Footnote 
77] This commission (known as the "Donner Commission") was the starting 
point for the most recent reform, which was enacted in 2005 and 
implemented in 2006. 

According to one expert who was involved with the Donner Commission, 
the commission was formed in an environment of political stalemate. 
Parties in the coalition government could not agree on a path for 
reform. Unions and employer groups were unsatisfied with progress on 
reform and they were considering developing a proposal. As the number 
of beneficiaries approached 1 million, the Minister of Social Affairs 
believed that forming a commission would produce meaningful reform that 
could break through the stalemate and the influence of unions and 
employers on disability policy. 

The Donner Commission was a small group that included members of each 
of the principal parties. Five of the seven members represented the 
five largest political parties in the Dutch government at the time, 
although-with the exception of Donner-the members did not hold national 
political offices. The sixth was an academic expert and the seventh was 
a civil servant who acted as a government liaison. In addition, there 
was a three person secretariat that produced reports and proposals for 
discussion by the commission. According to an expert familiar with the 
commission, the members were able to negotiate the reform package for 
their respective parties. The meetings of the commission were closed to 
the public. The commission drafted a report which included a set of 
recommendations, the primary one being an elimination of the partial 
disability benefit. The recommendations received much attention from 
the media once they were made public. 

Experts and government officials noted several reasons why the Donner 
Commission was successful at designing a reform that was adopted and 
appears to be effective. One expert said that the Donner Commission was 
formed in part because the "normal" political channels would be unable 
to reach an agreement on disability reform due to the controversy 
surrounding it. The commission also built consensus among different 
political parties; the fact that the commission had members from 
multiple parties also made the recommendations more difficult to 
ignore, according to one expert. 

Following the issuance of the Donner Commission's recommendations, the 
government asked that the Social and Economic Council (SER) provide 
comments on the proposals. The SER is a standing body that includes 
equal representation from labor, employers' groups, and government- 
appointed members that represent the public interests. The SER 
comments, either when requested by the government or by choice, on 
social and economic policy. In March 2002, the group issued its 
response to the Donner Commission's recommendations, unanimously 
recommending maintaining a partial disability benefit. According to an 
expert, vetting the recommendations through the SER brought about 
consensus because there was input to the reform from interests outside 
the government. 

In July 2002, the center-right Balkenende government came to power. One 
expert noted that the Minister of Social Affairs was committed to 
disability reform. However, in October 2002, another round of elections 
occurred, necessitating a delay in enactment of disability reform. The 
reform was considered by Parliament in an environment of fiscal crisis, 
as the Netherlands was in a recession. Government officials said that 
these fiscal issues were not the drivers of reform, but that the 
environment of fiscal crisis made reform of the disability program more 
politically feasible. 

Legislation was passed in 2005 and implemented in 2006 that contained 
elements of recommendations from both the Donner Commission and the 
SER. Experts said that the recent reform has had an initial impact of 
reducing the number of those on the disability program. 

This reform removed the partial disability benefit from the disability 
program and created a separate system for those on partial disability. 
In addition to establishing the separate partial disability system, 
reforms occurring in the same period: 

* increased the threshold to claim partial disability from 15 percent 
disabled to 35 percent disabled; 

* increased the benefit for those who were totally and permanently 
disabled from 70 percent of predisability wage to 75 percent of 
predisability wage; and; 

* mandated medical reassessment for those under age 50 receiving 
disability benefits. 

While it is not possible to cite the exact impact of the 2006 
disability reform, there has been a decrease in the number of people in 
the disability program along with a reduction in the number of new 
beneficiaries. The Netherlands government data show that the total 
number on disability dropped from 963,800 in 2004 to 845,000 in 2007. 
The data also show that inflow into the disability program has 
decreased in this period, from 74,800 in 2004 to 56,000 in 2007. 

Expectations: The Future of Reform: 

Experts said that there were pressures to soften the reform, although 
they disagreed as to whether there would be significant changes. 
According to government representatives, the Parliament is examining 
possible changes in the future to the benefit for those under age 18 
who are covered by the program, due to recent increases in use of the 
program by this age group. In addition, a longitudinal study is 
currently underway that seeks to determine what happens to workers who 
claim a disability over time under the new policy. Of particular 
interest to the authors is whether changes in the disability policy 
make it more likely for individuals to apply for other social programs, 
such as unemployment or welfare. 

[End of section] 

Appendix VI: Pension Reform in Germany: 

Reform Overview: Significance of the Reforms: 

In Germany, as elsewhere in Europe, population aging and the 
accompanying increase in the number of retirees relative to workers 
have financially strained the pay-as-you-go (PAYGO) defined-benefit 
public pension program. For this reason, policymakers have reformed the 
pension program over the last 15 years, first by introducing measures 
that made it less generous while preserving the basic structure of the 
system in 1992 and 1999, then by changing its structure in 2001. The 
monolithic PAYGO pension program then became a multipillar one with the 
addition of supplementary pension schemes-specifically, fully funded 
private and occupational schemes. Further changes in 2004 and 2007 
sought to put the pension system on a financially sustainable path. 

The reforms occurred incrementally as in the majority of countries 
around the world, but were significant in the sense that, taken 
together, they considerably transformed the world's oldest defined- 
benefit public pension program, according to experts. The reforms were 
initiated by the Christian Democratic Party/Christian Social Union 
(CDU/CSU) but continued when the Social Democratic Party (SPD) came to 
power in the late 1990s, as well as when a "Grand Coalition" brought 
the two parties together in government in 2005. The reforms took place 
in diverse political environments that were sometimes consensual, 
sometimes more adversarial. 

Origins and History of the Reforms: 

By the mid-1980s, long-term demographic projections showed that the 
public pension system would be financially unsustainable unless 
contribution rates were increased dramatically, or benefits cut 
substantially, according to an expert. The government of Chancellor 
Helmut Kohl introduced reforms in 1989-which became effective in 1992
-under favorable economic conditions. Experts generally view these 
reforms as consensual, with the main opposition party-the SPD-and the 
governing CDU/CSU party agreeing on the measures. Changes included 
indexing benefits to net wages instead of gross wages, which 
effectively decreased benefits because higher contributions and taxes 
reduced net wages relative to gross wages; increasing the normal 
retirement age from 63 to 65; and actuarially adjusting pensions, 
reducing incentives for early retirement, so those opting to receive 
benefits before 65 would face permanent reductions. 

However, the German reunification of 1989 made it clear that these 
reforms would not be sufficient to make the pension system financially 
sustainable for the next two decades, as expected. The unification 
brought a large number of new claimants from the former East Germany 
into the pension system, quickly putting pressure on its budget, 
according to government officials. Also, high contribution rates and 
the associated increase in nonwage labor costs became big issues in the 
mid-1990s following the economic recession of 1992-93. The political 
debate after 1995 emphasized pressures from globalization and European 
monetary integration. In particular, it focused attention on how high 
contribution rates would hinder Germany's competitiveness in the global 
economy and prevent job creation. 

New reforms passed in 1997-becoming law in 1999-but were politically 
contentious. The federal elections in 1998 increased partisanship as 
the reelection prospects of Chancellor Kohl, who had been in power 
since 1982, became uncertain, according to an expert. The reform 
provisions included gradually bringing women's and unemployed 
individuals' normal retirement age in line with men's at 65. However, 
in the charged political climate, the Social Democrats and labor unions 
opposed, and subsequently reversed, the introduction of a demographic 
factor that would have reduced the replacement rate of pensions. 

The failure to reduce nonwage labor costs provided momentum for further 
reforms once the SPD came into office under the leadership of 
Chancellor Gerhard Schroeder. Paradoxically, the new government's 
package of legislation in 2001 contained more drastic measures than 
those they opposed a few years earlier, as the following examples 
illustrate. 

* The Riester[Footnote 78] reforms transformed the public pension 
system into its current multipillar structure, with the traditional 
earnings-related statutory PAYGO pensions constituting the first 
pillar; occupational pensions making up the second; and the funded 
private pensions representing the third pillar.[Footnote 79] These 
private pensions were made voluntary, but the government sought to 
encourage people to take them up by offering direct subsidies or tax 
advantages.[Footnote 80] The relatively good performance of the stock 
market in the 1990s and the idea that everyone could benefit from it 
played a role in the promotion of these private pensions, according to 
an expert. The successful introduction of individual accounts in other 
countries, especially Sweden, which was viewed as a model by the Social 
Democrats, also played a role. 

* The Riester reforms stipulated a gradual reduction of the PAYGO first 
pillar pensions by modifying the adjustment formula. They also set to 
stabilize contributions rates at no more than 20 percent before 2020 
and 22 percent before 2030 for the first pillar[Footnote 81] to avoid 
negative effects on employment and growth. In addition, the reform 
package fixed a target for the replacement rate, promising that 
pensions would not fall below 67 percent of average net earnings, from 
the current 70 percent. The replacement rate was actually redefined 
insofar as it assumed the average worker would invest 4 percent of his 
or her gross earnings in the new voluntary supplementary pensions. Some 
experts view this replacement rate target more as a symbolic concession 
that "modernizers" within the SPD made to the "traditionalists" and to 
labor unions.[Footnote 82] The modernizers also managed to reach a 
consensus with the opposition led by the CDU. 

* The reforms included a built-in reexamination clause that called for 
government action if contribution and replacement rate targets were not 
expected to be met. This mechanism was triggered soon after as the 
pension system experienced a financial crisis in 2002-2003, which 
eventually led to further reforms. 

A deep economic downturn in 2002-03 caused, to a large extent, this 
financial crisis in the pension system. Unexpectedly high unemployment 
rates and dismal economic growth created a sense of urgency for 
reforms, according to an expert. In November 2002 immediately after 
winning a second term in the federal elections, Chancellor Schroeder's 
government set up a commission. The Rurup Commission[Footnote 83] was 
charged to make recommendations on ways to achieve sustainability in 
the pension system, as well as in health and long-term care insurance 
schemes. The commission was a way for the government to build consensus 
for further changes in these programs. It gave more legitimacy to 
reforms as the government lacked the strong mandate it enjoyed during 
its first term, with the CDU-led opposition clearly dominating the 
upper house-or second chamber-of Parliament, the Bundesrat, according 
to government officials. By deferring responsibility-and blame-to a 
commission of experts, the "modernizers" within the Social Democratic 
Party also sought to overcome intraparty opposition. 

The Rurup Commission was composed of 26 members with representatives of 
various interests in society, including labor unions and employers' 
organizations, and officials from lower levels of government. The 
subcommission on public pensions had about a third of the total number 
of members. It was successful in pushing for broad reforms, unlike the 
other two subcommissions on health and long-term care insurance, partly 
because the group agreed early on to avoid extreme ideological 
positions and find a rational, rule-bound middle ground acceptable to 
everyone, according to a member of this group. The subcommission on 
health insurance, on the other hand, was deeply divided and could not 
achieve a majority behind a policy model.[Footnote 84] Moreover, the 
media focused its attention on the bitter debates over health insurance 
financing as those became public, even though commission members were 
supposed to avoid public commentary and position taking, according to 
government officials. This allowed the pension group to work without 
close public scrutiny.[Footnote 85] 

All but one of the recommendations of the Rurup Commission regarding 
pensions-the 2004 reforms[Footnote 86]-became legislation fairly 
rapidly. Building on the Riester reforms, the new provisions included 
supplementing the pension benefit adjustment formula with a new 
"sustainability factor" to reflect changes in the number of workers 
supporting the system relative to pensioners;[Footnote 87] and 
loosening the rules and regulations governing the Riester pensions to 
encourage greater participation.[Footnote 88] The sustainability factor 
would lead to smaller pension adjustment, hence smaller increase in 
benefits, whenever the ratio of contributors to pensioners 
declines.[Footnote 89] The pension adjustment would be allowed to go 
down to zero but not lower to prevent pensions from declining, in 
nominal terms. The commission's projections showed that individuals 
choosing to invest in supplementary pensions, either in the second or 
third pillar, would be able to maintain a constant replacement 
rate.[Footnote 90] The sustainability factor was introduced to ensure 
that the pension system would be self-sustaining, balancing itself 
automatically in line with demographic development and employment 
levels.[Footnote 91] The expectation was that such a mechanism reduces 
the need for future reexamination and helps "depoliticize" the system. 

The 2004 reforms also stipulated that the government should report to 
the legislative bodies-the Bundestag and Bundesrat-every 4 years on 
whether targeted replacement rates for 2020 and 2030 are at risk, given 
the contributions rates, and if so, propose remedies. 

Only one recommendation of the Rurup Commission-the gradual increase in 
the retirement age from 65 to 67-was adopted later in 2007 by the 
current coalition government, which includes both the SPD and the CDU. 
The fact that this highly unpopular measure was postponed for several 
years can be interpreted as a sign that the reformers in the Schroeder 
government recognized the need to reach a compromise with its 
opponents, both inside and outside of the party, according to a German 
expert. But it was more a symbolic concession in the sense that the 
provision had not been scheduled to come into effect before 2011. 

The Reforms and the Public: 

According to an OECD official, the pension reforms were technical but 
efforts were made over several years to ensure that the public 
understood them. Experts also told us that the need for change in the 
public pension system in Germany has been discussed widely since the 
early 1990s. Successive governments in the last 15 years have made 
citizens aware of the necessity of reforms by using the recurring 
themes of population aging and high labor costs hampering economic 
growth. Reforms took place incrementally over this period of time. 
Overall, there was a mix of behind-the-scene work on the specifics and 
public information. 

Since 2004, every year individuals receive a report detailing their 
pension information.[Footnote 92] Financial institutions offering 
private pensions must also provide information on possible investments, 
portfolio structure, and risk potential to their clients before 
contracts are signed. 

Expectations: The Future of Reform: 

Government officials and some experts expect these reforms to be, on 
the whole, sufficient to ensure the sustainability of the pension 
system for the near future, and therefore do not foresee significant 
changes to the system. Officials seem cautiously optimistic that with 
time and the tax incentives and subsidies provided for supplementary 
pensions, people will enroll at sufficiently high rates. Experts 
estimate that the demand for Riester pensions doubled in 2004 after a 
slow start, then again in 2005 to reach more than 20 percent of all 
workers covered by the statutory first pillar, with another steep 
increase in 2006.[Footnote 93] Taken together, the three pillars of the 
pension system should ensure adequate pensions, according to officials. 

However, some characteristics of the system may lead to certain groups 
of people retiring with insufficient pensions. For example, 
supplementary private pensions are voluntary rather than mandated, and 
even though the take-up rate has been increasing, individuals may fail 
to contribute to them on a regular basis throughout their working life. 
Moreover, the market returns on these private pensions may be too 
modest. Also, low-income individuals may have less incentive to 
contribute to private pensions despite the high subsidies provided to 
them because these pensions would affect their eligibility for other 
means-tested payments, such as the minimum social security guarantee 
for old age. 

Figure 7: Key Events in German Pension Reform Process: 

[See PDF for image] 

This figure is a time-line of key events in German Pension Reform 
Process. The following data is depicted: 

Political Events: 
1982: CDU/CSU wins Parliament (with Free Democratic Party (FDP)); Kohl 
becomes Chancellor; 
1998: SPD wins Parliament (with the Green Party); Schroeder becomes 
Chancellor; 
2002: Rurup Commission formed; 
2005: Grand Coalition SPD and CDU/CSU formed after federal elections; 
Merkel becomes Chancellor. 

Legislative Events: 
1989: Pension Reform Act passed (effective 1992); 
1997: New reforms passed (effective 1999); 
2001: Riester Reforms passed; 
2004: Rurup proposals adopted (except retirement age change); 
2007: Retirement age change adopted. 

Source: GAO analysis. 

[End of figure] 

[End of section] 

Appendix VII: GAO Contact and Staff Acknowledgments: 

GAO Contact: 

Susan J. Irving, (202) 512-9142 or irvings@gao.gov: 

Acknowledgments: 

In addition to the contact named above, key contributors to this report 
were James McTigue, Assistant Director; Linda Baker, Analyst-In-Charge; 
Lisa Henson; Jeff Niblack; Lindsay Welter; and Seyda Wentworth. 

[End of section] 

Footnotes: 

[1] S. 2063 would establish a Bipartisan Task Force for Responsible 
Fiscal Action. A supermajority approval of the task force's report by 
12 of its 16 members is needed for the task force to make 
recommendations. A companion bill, HR 3655, was introduced in the House 
of Representatives on September 25, 2007. Securing America's Future 
Economy Commission Act, or SAFE Commission Act, S. 304, introduced on 
January 16, 2007, would establish a commission to-among other things-
-develop legislation to address the imbalance between long-term federal 
spending commitments and projected revenues. A companion bill, HR 3654, 
was introduced in the House on September 25, 2007. This proposal would 
establish a commission composed of 14 Congressional appointees, the 
Secretary of the Treasury and the Director of the Office of Management 
and Budget. 

[2] On January 22, 2007, Senators Feinstein and Domenici introduced the 
Social Security and Medicare Solvency Commission Act (S. 355) that 
would establish the National Commission on Entitlement Solvency to 
review and report to the President and the Congress on the Social 
Security and Medicare programs every 5 years with respect to their 
financial condition and long-term sustainability. On April 24, 2007, 
Senators Hagel and Webb, and Representatives Tanner and Castle 
introduced the Comprehensive Entitlement Reform Commission Act of 2007 
(S. 1195, HR 2024). On January 16, 2007, Representative McHenry 
introduced the Commission on Reforming Entitlement (CORE) Spending Act 
(HR 489). 

[3] GAO, The Long-Term Fiscal Challenge: Comments on the Bipartisan 
Task Force for Responsible Fiscal Action Act, GAO-08-238T (Washington, 
D.C.: Oct. 31, 2007). 

[4] See GAO, A Call for Stewardship: Enhancing the Federal Government's 
Ability to Address Key Fiscal and Other 21ST Century Challenges, GAO-08-
93SP (Washington, D.C.: December 2007). 

[5] See GAO, Social Security Reform: Other Countries' Experiences 
Provide Lessons for the United States, GAO06126 (Washington, D.C.: Oct. 
21, 2005). 

[6] See GAO, Social Security Reform: Analysis of Reform Models 
Developed by the President's Commission to Strengthen Social Security, 
GAO-03-310 (Washington, D.C.: Jan. 15, 2003); Social Security: 
Evaluating Reform Proposals, AIMD/HEHS-00-29 (Washington, D.C.: Nov. 4, 
1999); and Social Security: Criteria for Evaluating Social Security 
Reform Proposals, T-HEHS-99-94 (Washington, D.C.: Mar. 25, 1999). 

[7] See OECD's Health at a Glance 2007-OECD Indicators. See also 
European Commission, The Impact of Ageing on Public Expenditure: 
Projections for the EU-25 Member States on Pensions, Healthcare, Long- 
Term Care, Education and Unemployment Transfers (2004-50) (European 
Commission Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, 
2006). According to the European Commission, health care grew faster 
than GDP in all member countries of the European Union in the 1990s 
except Finland, Luxembourg, Denmark, and Sweden. In most EU countries 
spending on health care accounted for a growing share of total public 
spending in the past several decades, especially in the 1990s. 

[8] The public sector continued to be the main source of health 
financing in all OECD countries in 2005 except Mexico, the United 
States, and Greece. 

[9] Total U.S. health spending was 15.3 percent of GDP in 2005. The 
relative shares of public and private spending do not reflect 
government tax subsidies for private health care spending. In the 
United States, federal revenue losses due to health care-related tax 
preferences amounted to more than 1.5 percent of U.S. GDP in 2005. As a 
result, for the U.S., the private share is somewhat overstated and the 
public support understated. Health tax preferences also exist in some 
other countries, but information about these preferences is not readily 
available. 

[10] GAO, Budget Issues: Accrual Budgeting Useful in Certain Areas but 
Does Not Provide Sufficient Information for Reporting on Our Nation's 
Longer-Term Fiscal Challenge, GAO-08-206 (Washington, D.C.: Dec. 20, 
2007). 

[11] GAO, Social Security Reform: Implications of Different Indexing 
Choices, GAO-06-804 (Washington, D.C.: Sept. 14, 2006). It is important 
to note that the structure of public pension programs differs across 
countries, and hence may not be not strictly comparable. For example, 
contributions in some cases help finance maternity/paternity and 
unemployment benefits in addition to old age benefits. 

[12] For more information, see OECD, Pensions at a Glance: Public 
Policies Across OECD Countries (OECD, 2007 edition). In our 2005 
report, we noted that all OECD countries have made changes to their 
national pension systems, as did Chile. See GAO06126. 

[13] For women the reduction was 25 percent. 

[14] Gross replacement rate for male workers with average earnings. See 
table II.1.4 in OECD's 2007 Pensions at a Glance. For Sweden the 
estimated reduction was 17 percent; for Germany, 9 percent. 

[15] See European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and 
Financial Affairs, Public Finances in EMU-2007 (2007). 

[16] See Giuliano Bonoli, The Politics of Pension Reform: Institutions 
and Policy Change in Western Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University 
Press, 2000). 

[17] In its 2007 assessment of the long-term sustainability of public 
finances in the U.K., the European Commission stated that the U.K.'s 
proposed reforms to pensions addressed the concern of potentially 
inadequate provision in the future by strengthening the incentives for 
private savings for retirement and by increasing provision of public 
pensions, thus involving a slightly higher increase in public pension 
expenditure than previously projected; the reform also incorporates a 
planned gradual increase in the statutory state pension age. 

[18] For studies of recent reforms to European entitlement programs, 
see http://www.ces.fas.harvard.edu/conferences/bismarck/papers.html. 

[19] See OECD, Transforming Disability Into Ability: Policies to 
Promote Work and Income Security for Disabled People (2003), Table 7.1. 

[20] European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and 
Financial Affairs, European Economy: The Long-term Sustainability of 
Public Finance in The European Union (2006). 

[21] See Daniel Clegg, "Unemployment Policy Reform in 'Bismarckian' 
Welfare States: The Cases of Belgium, France, Germany and the 
Netherlands," paper prepared for the conference "A Long Goodbye to 
Bismarck? The Politics of Welfare Reforms in Continental Europe," Minda 
De Gunzburg Centre for European Studies, Harvard University, June 16 
and 17, 2006. 

[22] According to Swedish government officials, a negative correlation 
has existed in recent years between trends in unemployment and sickness 
receipt. Officials emphasized the importance of looking at the number 
of all those who are supported by government programs rather than being 
active in the labor force. 

[23] See Denmark's National Reform Programme: First Progress Report 
(October 2006). The European Commission cited the Welfare Agreement in 
its 2007 assessment of Denmark as a country with low risk with respect 
to the long-term sustainability of its public finances. 

[24] GAO, Older Workers: Policies of Other Nations to Increase Labor 
Force Participation, GAO-03-307 (Washington, D.C.: Feb. 13, 2003). 

[25] According to an OECD official, reforms in OECD countries focused 
on cost containment in the 1980s; in the 1990s, concerns focused on 
obtaining value for spending. A 2003 report by the European Council, 
Committee on Social, Health, and Family Affairs noted that in the 
1980s, health care reforms in Western European countries aimed at 
controlling spending; in the 1990s reforms were concerned with the 
quality of care and equity of access. For information on countries' 
health care systems and reforms, see the European Observatory on Health 
Systems and Policies, WHO European Centre for Health Policy, which 
publishes Health Systems in Transition (HiT) profiles. These are 
country-based reports that provide a detailed description of each 
health care system and of reform and policy initiatives in progress or 
under development. See [hyperlink, 
http://www.euro.who.int/observatory/ctryinfo/ctryinfo]. See also the 
International Network Health Policy and Reform, which monitors health 
policy trends and developments in 20 industrialized countries. See 
[hyperlink, http://www.hpm.org/en/index.html]. 

[26] In 2006. For more information on entitlement reform in the 
Netherlands, see The National Reform Programme for the Netherlands: 
2005-2008. 

[27] The commission was also unable to reach consensus on a proposal 
for long-term care. 

[28] In the 1980s in some countries, including Canada, Japan and the 
U.K., pension reforms that reduced benefits and made changes to other 
entitlement programs took place in a context of deficit reduction 
efforts. See GAO, Deficit Reduction: Experiences of Other Nations, GAO/ 
AIMD-95-30 (Washington, D.C.: Dec. 13, 1994). 

[29] The 2002 Rurup Commission's recommendation for a "sustainability 
factor" was enacted in 2004 and its recommendation for increasing the 
retirement age was enacted in 2007. 

[30] GAO-06-126. 

[31] Tetsuo Kabe, "Japan's Public Pension Reforms," Urban Institute 
International Conference on Social Security Reform, February 24, 2006. 

[32] One expert has described these concerns as creating an environment 
of "permanent austerity." See Paul Pierson, "Coping with Permanent 
Austerity: Welfare State Restructuring in Affluent Democracies" in The 
New Politics of the Welfare State, ed. Paul Pierson (Oxford: Oxford 
University Press, 2001). 

[33] An important condition for successfully moving to a single 
European currency is that economies of the participating countries 
should converge towards each other and remain healthy. Members of the 
European Union are expected to avoid excessive budgetary deficits 
(i.e., above 3 percent) and to ensure their debt to GDP ratio stays 
within the reference value limit of 60 percent as specified in the 
Maastricht Treaty. The budgets of EMU countries are monitored annually 
by the European Commission for compliance with the targets and for the 
long-term sustainability of their public finances. 

[34] Promulgated in 2000 and updated in 2005. The Netherlands' 2007 
report on its National Reform Programme can be found at [hyperlink, 
http://ec.europa.eu/growthandjobs/pdf/1206_annual_report_netherlands_en.
pdf]. 

[35] Various explanations have been given of the relationships between 
prompts and actual reform. Some observers believe that severe economic 
or budgetary problems are a precondition for countries to undertake 
reform. Other observers and government officials have noted that an 
environment of economic or fiscal crisis may facilitate public 
acceptance and hence enactment of reforms. Conversely, one quantitative 
study of 57 developed and developing countries has shown that countries 
with a high public debt to GDP ratio are less likely to privatize their 
pension programs (at least when pension liabilities are low or 
moderate). The study attributes a lack of reform in these types of 
circumstances to an inability to finance the transitional costs 
associated with moving from a public pay-as-you-go system to a system 
of fully funded individual accounts. 

[36] According to OECD, most countries set up ad-hoc commissions when 
pension reform processes are being launched. 

[37] On stages of reform, see Mitchell A. Orenstein, "How Politics and 
Institutions Affect Pension Reform in Three Postcommunist Countries" 
(Washington, D.C.: World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2310, March 
2000). Orenstein divides the reform process into three stages- 
commitment building, coalition building, and implementation. The 
commitment-building phase ends when the government creates a special 
office or working group with a clear mandate to develop and pursue a 
single type of pension reform. See also Sarah M. Brooks and R. Kent 
Weaver, "Lashed to the Mast?: The Politics of Notional Defined 
Contribution Pension Reforms" (Boston: Center for Retirement Research, 
January 2005). 

[38] See Val Koromzay, "Some Reflections on the Political Economy of 
Reform," Paper presented at the Conference on Economic Reforms for 
Europe: Growth Opportunities in an Enlarged European Union. Bratislava, 
Slovakia, March 18, 2004. 

[39] See Sanneke Kuipers, The Crisis Imperative: Crisis Rhetoric and 
Welfare State Reform in Belgium and the Netherlands in the Early 1990s 
(Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press, 2006). 

[40] The Commission's charter was to investigate the administration of 
social insurance programs including unemployment. 

[41] Inquiries of this type are customarily used to investigate alleged 
fraud and abuse or scandal. 

[42] Pension reform in Spain also involved the use of a parliamentary 
working group. 

[43] From 1994 to 1998 a second parliamentary group worked out the 
details of the reform. Following the 1994 elections, in which the 
Social Democratic party took the majority, the second working group was 
chaired by a Social Democrat who had played a key role in developing 
the reform concept put forward by the first working group. 

[44] Chancellor Schroeder also established other reform commissions 
including one on unemployment, the Hartz Commission. 

[45] The Commission had recommended abolishing the benefit for partial 
disability; the enacted proposal created retained a benefit for partial 
disability but made this a separate program. 

[46] See GAO03307. 

[47] In France a permanent government commission created in 2000 was 
tasked with monitoring the retirement system and making recommendations 
for change based on consultation. This group is composed of members of 
Parliament, representatives of employer and employee groups, and 
government officials. According to one expert this council established 
the concept for the 2003 pension reform. 

[48] Some observers have attributed this to the U.K. form of 
parliamentary government, which provides few hurdles to the exercise of 
power by a strong majority government. 

[49] In both cases, subsequent governments returned to the issue and 
continued to seek reforms. 

[50] Social Dialogue and Pension Reform, ed. Emmanuel Reynaud (Geneva: 
ILO, 2000). This 2000 study noted that in contrast to other countries 
studied (Sweden, Germany, Japan, Italy, and Spain), the will to seek 
consensus on pension reform was weak in the United Kingdom. 

[51] In Orenstein's view, tradeoffs exist across phases of reform in 
terms of who should be included in the process of proposal development. 
In his view, the smaller the number of key actors involved in design of 
reform at the commitment-building phase, the faster and more radical 
the reform. However, excluding key actors at the commitment-building 
phase (including those who have the political capacity to hobble or 
prevent reform) may cause them to mobilize effectively against reform 
in later phases. 

[52] See Brooks and Weaver. 

[53] GAO-06-126. 

[54] Other countries also have similar mechanisms. Canadian pension 
reform includes a re-visiting under specified circumstances as 
evaluated by their Chief Actuary. According to one expert, Canada's 
mechanism is not expected to be triggered. In France, an advisory 
council was created in 2000 to monitor the French retirement system and 
to put forward recommendations for public policy concerning retirement. 
The council includes members of Parliament, representatives of employer 
and employee groups, experts, and representatives of the state. 

[55] Sweden's reform also included a notional defined contribution 
(NDC) system for its pay-as-you-go defined benefit pension. This system 
automatically adjusts initial benefits to changes in longevity. Other 
countries including Italy have also adopted NDC systems as part of 
reform. 

[56] See our discussion of "hard" and "soft" triggers in Mandatory 
Spending: Using Budget Triggers to Constrain Growth, GAO-06-276 
(Washington, D.C.: Jan. 31, 2006). 

[57] See Rudolph G. Penner and C. Eugene Steuerle, Stabilizing Future 
Fiscal Policy: It's Time to Pull the Trigger (Washington, D. C.: The 
Urban Institute, Aug. 2007). 

[58] Italy has established a body tasked with monitoring pension 
finances and making the calculations that determine the notional 
defined contribution adjustment; the government and others have to 
agree on the adjustment. 

[59] One expert has noted that a shift to price-indexation of initial 
pension benefits in the U.K. reform of the 1980s was the first use of 
an automatic mechanism to adjust benefits. Over time this mechanism 
reduced benefits such that elderly poverty became an issue in the 
United Kingdom. Recent reforms include a modification to the 1980s 
formula. See Richard Jackson, "The 'State of the Art' in Entitlement 
Reform: Lessons from Abroad," Facing Facts Quarterly, Vol. II, No. 1 
(Washington, D.C.: Concord Coalition, Winter 2006). Jackson describes 
the U.K. change as a "blunt instrument" in comparison with recent NDC 
systems. 

[60] Brooks and Weaver have expressed the view that NDC-based reforms 
are likely to work best in countries that have the political capacity 
to achieve and sustain broad political agreement and the administrative 
capacity to produce independent forecasts of economic and demographic 
trends and complete and accurate records of earnings, as well as the 
capacity to ensure compliance and adequate understanding on the part of 
employers and employees. NDC-based reforms are less likely to work well 
where these capacities are lacking. 

[61] In 1983, a "hard" trigger was added to Social Security. Under 
current law, Social Security benefits for the elderly and disabled are 
updated annually by the change in inflation as measured by the Consumer 
Price Index. Should the trust fund ratio of payable benefits to 
reserves fall below a specified level, however, the annual update is to 
be the lower of price or wage change. The "triggering" trust fund 
percentage was 15 percent through 1988 and 20 percent for 1989 and 
later (42 U.S.C. §415(i)). To date, trust fund ratios have remained 
above the threshold. 

[62] Although the balance mechanism was mentioned in the 1998 reform 
legislation, it was not formalized until additional legislation was 
passed in 2001. Pay-as-you-go pension systems use contributions from 
current workers to fund current beneficiaries. 

[63] For further discussion of the programmatic changes to Sweden's 
pension system, see GAO, Older Workers: Policies of Other Nations to 
Increase Labor Force Participation, GAO-03-307 (Washington, D.C.: Feb. 
13, 2003). 

[64] Notional accounts hold contributions and investment earnings, but 
exist only on the books of the managing institution. At retirement, the 
accumulated notional capital in each account is converted to a stream 
of pension payments using a formula based on factors such as life 
expectancy at retirement. 

[65] The fund is the difference between contributions and expenditures 
in the pension system. The fund can include investments in any capital 
market instrument that is quoted and marketable, but the fund is 
subject to several restrictions on the allocation of the investments. 
From 1999 to 2001, the fund was used to help ease the transition to the 
new system. In the future, the fund will help finance pensions for baby 
boomers. 

[66] Social Democrats are a left-of-center party generally aligned with 
the interests of labor. 

[67] One academic expert told us he believed the Social Democrats tried 
to "bury" the issue in the committee. 

[68] Although seven parties were represented, five parties constituted 
an "inner circle" that negotiated the substantial reform elements, and 
later were the supporters of the reform. 

[69] The implementation group was chaired by a Social Democrat who was 
instrumental in developing the reform proposal in the 1991 group. 

[70] Individuals born between 1938 and 1953 will receive adjusted 
benefits from both systems, and individuals born after 1954 will 
receive pensions based completely on the new system. Individuals born 
before 1938 receive benefits based on the old system. 

[71] In the fall of 2006, after the committee released its report in 
2005, Sweden's government changed from Social Democrat control, to a 
center-right coalition government. 

[72] According to an official from Sweden's National Insurance Board, 
about 3 percent of Swedes report their knowledge of the pension system 
as "very good," and about one-third say their knowledge is "good" while 
about 50 percent reports that their knowledge is poor and 10 percent 
that their knowledge is very poor. 

[73] This benefit is less than the benefit one would receive if one 
qualified for full disability benefits. 

[74] The Buurmeijer Commission also looked at unemployment benefits. 

[75] This is part of the sickness insurance. Subsequent legislation 
increased the period of time that the employer paid. 

[76] "PEMBA," when translated to English, stands for "Act on Premium 
differentiation and market-competition in the disability insurances." 

[77] The Council of State is a constitutionally established advisory 
body to the government, which advises the Cabinet before laws are 
submitted to Parliament. Its membership includes members of the royal 
family and appointed members from various backgrounds including 
military, political, and business. 

[78] The reforms were passed through parliament by the labor minister 
Walter Riester. 

[79] Older workers with low incomes and those with reduced earning 
capacity are also entitled to a means-tested benefit. 

[80] The individual pensions are specially regulated contracts with 
financial institutions. People investing in these are guaranteed, at a 
minimum, to get back the amount they put in. The government subsidies 
are especially high for low-income people and those with children. 

[81] The contribution rate on this earnings-related pillar is shared 
equally between employers and employees. 

[82] Some experts view fixing targets for both contribution and 
replacement rates as contradictory. 

[83] Bert Rurup chaired the commission, more formally called the 
Commission for Sustainability in Financing the German Social Insurance 
Systems. 

[84] The Rurup Commission was more limited in its options for health 
insurance reform, according to an expert, because of strong organized 
interests-doctors, hospitals, pharmaceutical companies, health 
insurers, etc.-and the conflicting political values behind the 
different financing models. Some observers also believe that the 
Federal Minister for Health and Social Policy Ulla Schmidt's choice of 
appointments on the commission may have led to this division. 

[85] The opposition led by the CDU set up its own Herzog Commission to 
look into the same issues. The two commissions worked closely together 
behind the scenes on pension reform, according to a member of the Rurup 
Commission. 

[86] The reforms were passed under the Old-Age Pensions Insurance 
Sustainability Act. 

[87] Benefits are computed as follows: for each year of contributions, 
an individual receives pension points. At retirement, the sum of 
pension points are multiplied by a pension point value currently set at 
about 23 euros. This pension point value is adjusted annually by an 
index that is based on net wage growth and the sustainability factor. 
All German pensions-both for new and current retirees -are affected by 
these adjustments. 

[88] For example, individuals eligible for government subsidies for the 
supplementary pensions now include all taxpayers. Also, the procedures 
for granting government subsidies have been simplified. 

[89] Conversely, pension adjustment would increase if the number of 
working people contributing to the pension system rises relative to the 
number of individuals receiving pensions. 

[90] With the Rurup Commission's economic and demographic projections, 
pension replacement rates will initially decline then reach their 2004 
level by 2030. 

[91] Hence, the sustainability factor takes into account not only 
changes in life expectancy but also fertility rates, immigration, as 
well as other factors. 

[92] Specifically, individuals from age 27 receive an annual pension 
statement; from age 54, they receive a more detailed statement every 3 
years. The report includes information on their entitlements and their 
expected pension. People can also check their report online. 

[93] Axel Boersch-Supan, Anette Reil-Held, and Christina B. Wilke, "How 
a Unfunded Pension System Looks like Defined Benefits but Works like 
Defined Contributions: The German Pension Reform," Paper written for 
the Fundacion Carolina (May 31, 2007). 

[End of section] 

GAO's Mission: 

The Government Accountability Office, the audit, evaluation and 
investigative arm of Congress, exists to support Congress in meeting 
its constitutional responsibilities and to help improve the performance 
and accountability of the federal government for the American people. 
GAO examines the use of public funds; evaluates federal programs and 
policies; and provides analyses, recommendations, and other assistance 
to help Congress make informed oversight, policy, and funding 
decisions. GAO's commitment to good government is reflected in its core 
values of accountability, integrity, and reliability. 

Obtaining Copies of GAO Reports and Testimony: 

The fastest and easiest way to obtain copies of GAO documents at no 
cost is through GAO's Web site [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov]. Each 
weekday, GAO posts newly released reports, testimony, and 
correspondence on its Web site. To have GAO e-mail you a list of newly 
posted products every afternoon, go to [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov] 
and select "Subscribe to Updates." 

Order by Mail or Phone: 

The first copy of each printed report is free. Additional copies are $2 
each. A check or money order should be made out to the Superintendent 
of Documents. GAO also accepts VISA and Mastercard. Orders for 100 or 
more copies mailed to a single address are discounted 25 percent. 
Orders should be sent to: 

U.S. Government Accountability Office: 
441 G Street NW, Room LM: 
Washington, D.C. 20548: 

To order by Phone: 
Voice: (202) 512-6000: 
TDD: (202) 512-2537: 
Fax: (202) 512-6061: 

To Report Fraud, Waste, and Abuse in Federal Programs: 

Contact: 

Web site: [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/fraudnet/fraudnet.htm]: 
E-mail: fraudnet@gao.gov: 
Automated answering system: (800) 424-5454 or (202) 512-7470: 

Congressional Relations: 

Gloria Jarmon, Managing Director, JarmonG@gao.gov: 
(202) 512-4400: 
U.S. Government Accountability Office: 
441 G Street NW, Room 7125: 
Washington, D.C. 20548: 

Public Affairs: 

Chuck Young, Managing Director, youngc1@gao.gov: 
(202) 512-4800: 
U.S. Government Accountability Office: 
441 G Street NW, Room 7149: 
Washington, D.C. 20548: