This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-02-828 
entitled 'Restructured Electricity Markets: California Market Design 
Enabled Exercise of Market Power' which was released on June 21, 2002. 

This text file was formatted by the U.S. General Accounting Office 
(GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part of a 
longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every 
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of 
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text 
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the 
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided 
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed 
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic 
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail 
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this 
document to Webmaster@gao.gov. 

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work 
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the 
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this 
material separately. 

United States General Accounting Office: 
GAO: 

Report to Congressional Requesters: 

June 2002: 

Restructured Electricity Markets: 

California Market Design Enabled Exercise of Market Power: 

GAO-02-828: 

Contents: 

Letter: 

Results in Brief: 

Background: 

Suppliers Exercised Market Power during Periods of Tight Demand and 
Supply Balances: 

Market Design in California Enabled Exercise of Market Power: 

Conclusion: 

Objectives, Scope, and Methodology: 

Appendix I: Determining the Existence of Market Power and Impact of 
CAISO Price Caps: 

Appendix II: Key Events during Electricity Restructuring in California: 

Appendix III: Summary of Studies on Market Power: 

Appendix IV: Bibliography of Selected Studies: 

Appendix V: GAO Contacts and Staff Acknowledgments: 

GAO Contacts: 

Acknowledgments: 

Tables: 

Table 1: Studies of Market Power in California’s Restructured 
Electricity Market: 

Table 2: Price Regression Results: 

Figures: 

Figures
Figure 1: Average Monthly Prices of Electricity in California, April
1998-February 2002: 

Figure 2: Baseline Relationship between Electricity Demand and Prices 
(August through October 1998): 

Figure 3: Comparison of Prices and Demand (Baseline and August through 
October 2000): 

Figure 4: Demand and Prices: 

Abbreviations: 

CAISO: California Independent System Operator: 

FERC: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission: 

MWh: megawatt hour: 

[End of section] 

United States General Accounting Office: 
Washington, DC 20548: 

June 21, 2002: 

The Honorable Jay Inslee: 
The Honorable Peter DeFazio: 
House of Representatives: 

Electricity is vital to our daily lives and our national economy. The 
United States’ electricity industry is in the midst of major change, 
and the results of this change will affect all consumers. Historically, 
utility monopolies have generated electricity and sold it to consumers 
at prices set by state regulators. Now, in as many as 24 states, 
numerous private companies compete to sell electricity at either the 
wholesale or retail level at prices determined by the market forces of 
demand and supply. This change, commonly referred to as restructuring, 
is being driven by federal legislation and regulatory rules as well as 
by state actions. Restructuring is intended to improve efficiency in 
the industry and ultimately lower consumer prices. 

California is part of a broader western market, and electricity is 
routinely bought and sold across state and national boundaries. For 
example, California has historically imported as much as 20 percent of 
its electricity from surrounding states—such as Arizona, Oregon, and 
Washington as well as from Canada and Mexico. In addition, California 
has exported electricity during periods when supply has exceeded demand 
in the state. As in other markets, private electricity suppliers will 
try to sell their electricity in whatever location they can get the 
highest price. As a result, if prices rise in one state, supply will 
flow into that state from surrounding regions, and this potentially 
causes prices to rise in those regions as well. 

California’s electricity industry began operating in a restructured 
market in April 1998. As part of the state’s restructuring plan, the 
three privately owned utilities[Footnote 1] operating in the 
state—serving about 75 percent of California’s customers—were 
encouraged to sell much of their electricity generating capacity to 
private generating companies, referred to as wholesale suppliers, to 
enhance competition in the wholesale electricity market. To provide 
electricity to consumers, the three utilities then had to rely largely 
on these wholesale suppliers. Wholesale market prices—the prices 
utilities paid for electricity they sold to consumers—were determined 
in an auction run by a “power exchange,” in which retailers purchased 
electricity from wholesale suppliers, generally no more than a day in 
advance of the delivery date. At the outset of restructuring, retail
prices charged by the utilities to consumers were still determined by 
the California Public Utilities Commission. As such, retail prices were 
initially frozen at a level 10 percent below the pre-restructuring 
rate, with full retail competition and unregulated retail prices 
intended to begin later. Finally, the plan set up the California 
Independent System Operator (CAISO), a nonprofit, private corporation 
charged with managing the transmission system in the state and 
balancing demand and supply, at the last minute, to ensure reliability 
of supply. California’s market design was approved by the Federal 
Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC), which has authority over the 
design and operation of wholesale electricity markets. 

For two years, the state had relatively low wholesale electricity 
prices. Beginning in May 2000, however, wholesale prices rose 
dramatically in California and stayed relatively high for about a year. 
Causes for the high prices included fast-growing demand, slow-growing 
supply, and unusually dry and warm weather in the region, which led to 
decreased availability of electricity imported from surrounding areas 
to California. 

State officials and others also claimed that wholesale suppliers were 
exercising market power to raise prices above competitive levels. In 
this context, market power refers to the ability of individual sellers 
of electricity to charge prices above competitive levels. The 
competitive price is, by common definition, equal to the additional 
costs that would be incurred to produce an additional unit of 
electricity sold in the market. As long as sufficient supplies exist, 
the competitive price is roughly proportional to the fuel costs 
required to generate the next unit of power. However, when supplies 
grow increasingly scarce, leading to a tight balance between demand and 
supply, generating costs can rise dramatically because they include the 
costs of running generating units at higher than normal rates, thereby 
increasing the likelihood of breakdowns. At the point that all 
available generating capacity is in use, the competitive price will 
rise until demand equals supply at that price. 

It is possible for market power to be acquired and used through 
legitimate means. For example, a patent on a new medicine may enable a 
drug company legally to charge prices above the costs of producing the 
drug, or a gasoline station owner on a busy corner may be able to 
charge higher prices than a competitor on a less traveled block, even 
if they pay the same amount for the gas they sell. However, federal 
antitrust laws are violated if a company achieves, protects, or expands 
its market power through anticompetitive business practices such as 
colluding with its competitors to raise prices. 

Because of concerns about market power, California officials appealed to
FERC to mitigate the high prices. FERC is responsible for ensuring that
electricity prices are “just and reasonable.” If FERC determines that 
prices are not just and reasonable, FERC has authority to order refunds 
or make market changes, such as temporarily capping wholesale prices. 
Such a price cap would place a limit on the price suppliers could 
charge for their electricity. 

In summer 2000, California used its authority, granted by FERC, to
implement price caps in the wholesale market to mitigate the high 
prices. Further, in December 2000, FERC imposed its own price cap in an 
attempt to mitigate prices, although it allowed suppliers to sell at 
prices exceeding this cap if they could demonstrate that their costs 
were high enough to warrant such a price. All of the wholesale price 
caps imposed in 2000 were set at levels far above the frozen retail 
prices. In winter and spring of 2001—after many months of paying high 
wholesale prices and selling the electricity at much lower frozen 
retail prices—two of the three utilities became insolvent and were 
unable to purchase sufficient electricity to serve their customers. The 
state then began buying electricity from the market in the utilities’ 
stead and eventually negotiated long-term contracts with wholesale 
suppliers to provide electricity to the state over periods of time as 
long as 20 years in the future. 

Wholesale prices remained relatively high until about June 2001, when
prices fell. A combination of events—cooler than usual weather, 
increased supply from the addition of new generating facilities, state 
conservation efforts, long-term purchases of electricity by the state, 
and a new regionwide price cap imposed by FERC—has been credited by 
various state, federal, and industry sources with causing prices to 
fall. The state is currently reviewing and redesigning its electricity 
market in order to ensure that the events that led to the high prices 
in 2000 and 2001 do not reoccur. The state is seeking approval from 
FERC for the new design. 

You asked us to determine (1) whether wholesale suppliers of electricity
exercised market power by raising prices above competitive levels after
restructuring, and if so, (2) what role, if any, the design of 
California’s market played in facilitating the suppliers’ ability to 
exercise market power. To address your questions, we performed 
statistical and other analyses of electricity market data from April 
1998 through October 2000; reviewed numerous studies; and interviewed 
academics, industry experts, and analysts. Our analysis of market power 
is focused on the late summer and early fall of 2000. Because we did 
not have access to detailed company-specific data, we were unable to 
draw conclusions about the behavior of individual wholesale suppliers 
in 2000. In particular, we did not have data that would have enabled us 
to evaluate the effects of recently revealed trading strategies by 
Enron, wholesale suppliers, or other companies trading in electricity 
markets. Further, we did not assess whether the high prices experienced 
in California were the result of violations of federal antitrust or 
other laws relating to the sale of electric power. Such assessments 
fall under the jurisdiction of state attorneys general or federal 
entities such as the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade 
Commission. A number of lawsuits have been filed concerning various 
aspects of the California electricity market. Among these, are pending 
lawsuits alleging antitrust, fraud, and other violations of law. 
Appendix I provides a complete discussion of our methodology. 

Results in Brief: 

Our analysis and other studies found evidence that wholesale electricity
suppliers exercised market power by raising prices above competitive
levels during the summer of 2000 and at other times after restructuring.
Neither our analysis nor the other studies addressed whether any market
power exercised in California was in violation of federal or other laws
pertaining to the sale of electricity. However, our analysis and other
studies found that during some periods, prices did not follow patterns
consistent with prices under competitive conditions. For example, 
several studies concluded that wholesale suppliers were able to 
exercise market power by withholding electricity from the market, only 
making it available at the last minute when buyers were desperate to 
acquire enough electricity to meet demand and therefore willing to pay 
higher prices. As part of our analysis, we also found evidence of 
increasingly tight balances between demand and supply during the same 
period—a hot summer caused demand to rise, while dry weather the 
previous winter meant that hydroelectricity was in short supply. 
Because tight demand and supply balances would also lead to higher than 
normal prices, even under competitive conditions, we could not isolate 
how much of the relatively high prices was due to the exercise of 
market power. Other factors, such as environmental constraints on some 
electricity generators and higher fuel costs, were also identified by 
the other studies as contributing factors to the high prices. 

The design of California’s electricity market enabled individual 
wholesale suppliers of electricity to exercise market power. In 
addition, once prices rose, in part as a result of market power, the 
design lacked effective mitigation strategies to return prices to 
competitive levels. Prominent experts on market design and industry 
experts generally agree that two principal market design flaws 
increased wholesale suppliers’ incentive and ability to raise prices 
above competitive levels: (1) retail prices were frozen, and (2) with 
few exceptions, the California Public Utilities Commission prohibited 
or discouraged long-term contracts between utilities and wholesale 
suppliers. The experts and analysts concluded that the frozen retail 
electricity prices in California made it more profitable for suppliers 
to raise prices, because when they did, consumers did not reduce their 
use of electricity. Because retail prices were frozen, consumers had no 
financial incentive to reduce their demand when wholesale prices rose 
in summer 2000. This is unlike most other markets, in which consumers 
choose to buy less when prices rise. When consumers respond to prices 
in this way, suppliers know that if they raise their prices, they will 
lose some of their business. Concerning the lack of long-term contracts 
between utilities and wholesale suppliers, the experts and analysts 
concluded that this situation increased suppliers’ ability to exercise 
market power because, without contractual obligations to generate 
electricity, suppliers could withhold part of their supply. As a 
result, electric utilities—required by design to serve all of consumer
demand in their service areas—had to compete to purchase increasingly
scarce electricity. Under these circumstances, wholesale suppliers were
able to raise their prices above competitive levels. Our analysis shows 
that California’s market design also lacked effective price mitigation 
strategies to be used once the exercise of market power was suspected. 
More specifically, in 2000, price caps imposed by the California 
Independent System Operator were ineffective in reducing prices to 
competitive levels, allowing the high prices to persist. Other studies 
and expert opinion also concluded that these price caps did not work, 
in part because they applied only to the state of California, leading 
to problems getting needed electricity into the state when electricity 
prices in other states rose above the California price caps. 

Background: 

Prior to restructuring, the electricity industry in California was 
organized around three regulated monopoly utilities, which were 
responsible for ensuring that electricity demand and supply were 
balanced at all times in order to maintain a reliable electricity 
system. The utilities owned and operated the electricity generating 
facilities as well as the electricity transmission system (i.e., the 
actual wires that carry electricity from generators to final 
consumers). The utilities sold electricity to consumers at prices 
determined by the state’s Public Utilities Commission—a state 
regulatory agency. Charges to cover the costs of generating the 
electricity as well as the costs of maintaining and operating the 
transmission system were included in the retail electricity prices set 
by the commission. Utilities were allowed to earn a “normal rate of 
return” on all approved capital expenditures required to build 
generating facilities and the transmission system itself. 

Seeking to improve efficiency and reduce electricity prices, California
began restructuring its electricity market during the 1990s. As part of 
the state’s restructuring plan, the utilities were encouraged to sell 
much of their generating capacity to private companies. This 
divestiture was intended to increase the number of competitors in the 
wholesale electricity market. The plan also set up the California 
Independent System Operator (CAISO), a private nonprofit corporation 
charged with managing the transmission system in the state and 
balancing demand and supply to ensure reliability of the system. Under 
the plan, the utilities would still own some generating capacity and 
own and maintain the transmission system. In the restructured market, 
which formally opened on April 1, 1998, private generators were able to 
sell electricity to the utilities through the newly created California 
Power Exchange in daily and hourly auctions. The power exchange was 
intended to be the primary market for wholesale electricity sold in the 
state. To ensure that the power exchange was a competitive market with 
many suppliers, the Public Utilities Commission required the utilities 
to sell their remaining generating capacity into the power exchange 
market. The Public Utilities Commission also limited the utilities’ 
ability to enter into long-term contracts to purchase electricity
wholesale, which effectively required them to purchase almost all of 
their electricity needs from the power exchange. As a result of these 
actions, most electricity purchases occurred in the short 
term—generally, at most one day ahead of when the electricity was 
needed. 

Under restructuring, retail prices were frozen, while wholesale prices 
were to be determined by market conditions of demand and supply. In an
attempt to ensure that consumers received some immediate benefits from
restructuring, California’s restructuring legislation required retail 
prices be frozen for up to 4 years at a level 10 percent below the 
prices that were in effect immediately prior to restructuring. Policy 
makers anticipated that the reduced retail prices would be higher than 
wholesale prices and would therefore allow the utilities to continue to 
recover costs they incurred in the old regulated market and that had 
not yet been recouped. Wholesale prices were determined in the power 
exchange market, and the CAISO bought some electricity near the last 
minute to maintain a precise balance between demand and supply. FERC’s 
authority was unchanged; the agency continues to monitor the 
functioning of wholesale markets and retains responsibility for 
ensuring that wholesale prices are just and reasonable. 

For the first two years of California’s restructured market, overall
wholesale prices were fairly low, averaging about $33 per megawatt-hour
(MWh)[Footnote 2] compared with the frozen retail prices, which were 
set at about $65 per MWh. However, overall wholesale prices rose 
significantly in May 2000 and remained very high through May 
2001.[Footnote 3] These overall prices reached an all-time peak in 
December 2000 of $317 per MWh. Figure 1 shows the monthly average 
overall prices since April 1998, when the restructured market began 
operating, through February 2002. 

Figure 1: Average Monthly Prices of Electricity in California, April 
1998-February 2002: 

[Refer to PDF for image] 

This figure is a vertical bar graph depicting the average monthly 
prices of electricity in California, April 1998-February 2002. The 
price is indicated in dollars per MWh. The lowest monthly price appears 
to be about $20 in May and June of 1998. The highest price is $317 in 
December of 2000. 

Source: GAO’s presentation of data from CAISO. 

[End of figure] 

As we reported in June 2001, average wholesale prices of electricity 
sold through the power exchange during the months of May through 
December 2000 were between 2 and 13 times higher than prices in the 
same months of the previous year.[Footnote 4] In addition, there were 
frequent periods, especially in the winter of 2000-2001, when the 
electricity system was in danger of service disruptions, and there were 
a number of days when rolling blackouts occurred. During this period, 
two of the state’s three major utilities became insolvent and were 
unable to pay for their purchases of electricity. The California Power 
Exchange ceased doing business in January 2001 and later declared 
bankruptcy, as the state assumed responsibility for buying electricity 
on behalf of the utilities. (See app. II for a timeline of key events 
occurring in the California electricity market.) 

Various factors have been cited as contributing to California’s high
electricity prices. 

* Increased demand for electricity combined with a shortage of supply
created increased scarcity beginning in May 2000. As we noted in our 
June 2001 report, demand for electricity rose by as much as 13 percent 
from 1995 through 2000, while supply growth did not keep pace.[Footnote 
5] 

* Imported electricity from the Pacific Northwest, which California
depended upon to meet its needs, was less available because an extremely
dry winter in 2000 had reduced hydropower generation. In addition,
imports from southwestern states were less available because higher-
than-normal temperatures increased electricity demand in those states. 

* Costs of generating electricity rose in 2000. In particular, prices 
of natural gas—the fuel used to generate as much as 40 percent of 
California’s electricity—rose in 2000 compared to 1998 and 1999 prices. 
Also the costs of emissions permits, which some generating plants are 
required to own in order to operate, also rose in 2000. 

* California state officials and others cited the exercise of market 
power by suppliers as a cause of the dramatically higher prices. 

California officials attempted to mitigate high wholesale electricity 
prices in several ways. The CAISO attempted to control wholesale price
increases by using a price cap to limit the maximum price it would pay 
for electricity it purchased. During the summer of 2000, this maximum 
price was lowered twice: from $750 to $500 per MWh in July and again 
from $500 to $250 in August. Despite the caps, overall wholesale 
electricity prices remained higher than in the previous two years. As a 
result, California requested assistance from FERC. In December 2000, 
FERC implemented its own mitigation strategy that capped wholesale 
prices at $150 per MWh, but allowed suppliers to charge higher prices 
if they could demonstrate to FERC that their costs of generating the 
electricity exceeded the price cap. Even after FERC’s actions, prices 
remained much higher than normal through May 2001. 

In June 2001, FERC implemented a region-wide price cap that effectively 
limited prices to a maximum of about $92 per MWh in all western 
states.[Footnote 6] The state also took steps to expedite the siting of 
new power plants, promote energy conservation (in part by raising 
retail prices), and to negotiate long-term contracts with electricity 
suppliers. In June 2001, overall wholesale prices fell dramatically and 
continued to decline for several more months, eventually dropping to 
about $40 per MWh as of December 2001. Numerous reasons have been 
advanced for these decreasing prices, including the price mitigation 
efforts by the state and FERC. In addition, demand was lower because of 
moderate weather conditions, and electricity-generating costs fell due 
to lower costs for purchasing natural gas. 

Despite the current moderate electricity prices and estimates of enough
electricity to meet the state’s needs for the summer of 2002, 
California’s electricity market faces an uncertain future for a number 
of reasons: (1) FERC’s region-wide price caps are scheduled to expire 
September 30, 2002; (2) CAISO is still in the process of redesigning 
the electricity market and will seek approval from FERC for their new 
design; and (3) California officials are attempting to renegotiate many 
of the long-term contracts they signed with wholesale electricity 
suppliers in early 2001 because the prices they negotiated are much 
higher than current market prices. Further, as we recently reported, 
many proposals for new power plants in California have been canceled 
because of factors such as the national economic slowdown; lower 
electricity prices; and the increased risk of entering a market where 
the market design and rules are uncertain.[Footnote 7] 

Suppliers Exercised Market Power during Periods of Tight Demand and 
Supply Balances: 

Our analysis found that electricity suppliers exercised market power by
raising prices above competitive levels during some periods after the
restructured market opened. In particular, we found that in parts of 
2000, electricity prices did not follow the usual pattern of rising 
during the high-demand hours and falling during low-demand 
hours—rather, the highest prices were not found in the hours of highest 
demand. In addition, numerous studies conducted by prominent economists 
and other industry analysts also found evidence that individual 
suppliers exercised market power by raising their prices above 
competitive levels during certain periods. In explaining the high 
prices, the studies pointed to other factors as well, such as 
environmental constraints on some generators, higher fuel costs, and a 
generally tighter supply-demand balance, which increased suppliers’ 
costs and contributed to relatively scarce supply during 2000. Table 1 
summarizes our findings and the results of the other studies. 

Table 1: Studies of Market Power in California’s Restructured 
Electricity Market: 

Study/Authors: GAO analysis; 
Period studied: April 1998-October 2000; 
Methodology: Estimated the relationship between market price and total 
demand for electricity during a baseline period. Estimated the 
relationship between price and demand in August-October 2000 period—a 
high price period—and compared it to the baseline. Used other market 
data to attempt to explain observed differences. Remaining unexplained
differences attributed in part to market power. 
Results or findings: Prices across different levels of demand were 
inconsistent with baseline relationship between price and demand. Other 
factors—including fuel costs and levels of imported electricity, total
demand, and in-state generation—did not explain the different pattern.
Price pattern was consistent with market power being exercised in off-
peak hours. 

Study/Authors: Berkeley/Stanford study; 
Period studied: June 1998-October 2000; 
Methodology: Estimated the marginal cost of supplying electricity and 
compared this cost to market prices. Prices greater than marginal cost 
were deemed to imply exercise of market power. 
Results or findings: Market power was exercised in peak demand periods 
in 1998 and 1999, and more extensively in summer 2000. Fifty-one 
percent of total electricity expenditures in summer 2000 were 
attributable to market power. 

Study/Authors: MIT study; 
Period studied: June-September, 2000; 
Methodology: Estimated competitive benchmark prices. Compared actual 
market prices with the benchmark. Prices higher than benchmark were
deemed to imply exercise of market power. 
Results or findings: Prices far exceeded competitive levels during 
study period. Fuel costs, emissions permit prices, and other factors 
accounted for some of high prices. Market power accounted for the rest. 

Study/Authors: CAISO-A study; 
May-November, 2000; 
Methodology: Reviewed individual suppliers’ offers to sell electricity. 
Compared the offered prices with estimated marginal costs of generating 
power for each supplier. Offered prices higher than marginal costs were
deemed to imply exercise of market power. 
Results or findings: Some offers to sell were inconsistent with 
competitive behavior. Evidence indicates that suppliers withheld
electricity to drive up prices. 

Study/Authors: CAISO-B study; 
Period studied: April 1998-February 2001; 
Methodology: Estimated baseline marginal costs of generating 
electricity that would occur under competition. Compared market prices 
to these costs. Prices higher than marginal costs were deemed to imply 
exercise of market power. 
Results or findings: Suppliers exercised market power during the study 
period. Overall costs to state attributed to market power: $6.2 
billion. 

Study/Authors: California State Auditor Study; 
Period studied: April 1998-December 2001; 
Methodology: Reviewed other studies, interviewed experts, reviewed 
bidding data. 
Results or findings: Suppliers deliberately attempted to manipulate 
prices. Suppliers withheld supply, causing CAISO to pay high prices to 
maintain system balance and avoid blackouts. 

Source: GAO’s analysis and GAO’s presentation of data from other 
studies. 

[End of table] 

Our Analysis Found Suppliers Exercised Market Power: 

To determine whether there was evidence that wholesale electricity
suppliers exercised market power in California, we evaluated data from
August through October 1998—a period of relatively low wholesale
prices—to establish a competitive baseline relationship between
wholesale electricity prices and the level of demand. We selected this
baseline period because previous studies indicated that prices during 
the period were, for the most part, competitive. Then we compared the
baseline to the period from August through October 2000, when wholesale
prices were on average much higher, to determine whether the pattern of
prices was consistent for comparable situations in the two periods. 
[Footnote 8] Our analysis used price data from the power exchange 
market and demand data from CAISO. 

Under competitive conditions, prices of electricity are expected to 
follow a pattern in which high prices correspond to hours of the day in 
which demand for electricity is high and low prices correspond to low-
demand hours. This pattern occurs because competitive electricity 
prices reflect the changing costs of producing electricity. The 
competitive price of a MWh of electricity is equal to the additional 
amount it would cost to generate an additional megawatt-hour, once all 
current demand is met. This additional cost is commonly referred to as 
the marginal cost. The marginal cost of generating electricity rises as 
more electricity is produced, because different generators use 
different types and amounts of fuel. For example, hydroelectric and 
nuclear generating plants have very low fuel costs, while natural-gas-
burning plants have higher fuel costs. Generating plants with low 
marginal costs generally operate during more hours of the day than 
those with higher marginal costs—the highest-cost plants operate only 
during the very highest demand hours and may even sit idle most of the 
year. Therefore, under competition, the rising marginal cost of 
electricity leads to high prices when demand is high and low prices
during low-demand periods. 

Figure 2 shows actual average demand and prices for different hours of
the day from August through October 1998, the period that we used as our
baseline. As the figure shows, prices are generally lower during low-
demand hours and higher during high-demand hours. 

Figure 2: Baseline Relationship between Electricity Demand and Prices 
(August through October 1998): 

[Refer to PDF for image] 

This figure is a combination vertical bar and line graph. The vertical 
bar depict electricity (demand in thousands of MWhs) in August through 
October 1998 during the following hours of the day: 
1-4 A.M.
5-8 A.M. 
9 A.M. -12 P.M. 
1-4 P.M. 
5-8 P.M. 
9 P.M.-12 A.M. 

A line on the graph depicts prices (in dollars per MWh)in August 
through October 1998 during the same hours of the day. Both demand and 
prices peaked during the 1-4 P.M. time period. 

Source: GAO’s presentation of price data from the California Power 
Exchange and demand data from CAISO. 

[End of figure] 

Figure 3 illustrates the price and demand patterns we observed during 
the baseline period compared to those for the period from August through
October 2000. In comparing this baseline relationship to the prices and
demand observed from August through October 2000, we found that
average prices were much higher during the 2000 period than in the
baseline. Other studies attributed part of this increase in prices to 
the exercise of market power. In addition, we found that the 
relationship between prices and demand observed during the 2000 period 
was not consistent with what would be expected under competitive 
conditions. Specifically, during the period analyzed, average prices 
during the heaviest demand hours were actually lower than in 
surrounding, lower-demand hours. 

Figure 3: Comparison of Prices and Demand (Baseline and August through 
October 2000)[A]: 

[Refer to PDF for image] 

This figure is a combination multiple vertical bar and multiple line 
graph. The vertical bars depict electricity demand (in thousands of 
MWhs) in August through October 1998 and in August through October 2000 
during the following hours of the day: 
1-4 A.M.
5-8 A.M. 
9 A.M. -12 P.M. 
1-4 P.M. 
5-8 P.M. 
9 P.M.-12 A.M. 

Lines on the graph depict prices (in dollars per MWh)in August through 
October 1998 and in August through October 2000 during the same hours 
of the day. Demand peaked during the 1-4 P.M. hours in both 1998 and 
2000. Price peaked during the 1-4 P.M. hours in 1998 and during the 9 
P.M.-12 A.M. hours in 2000. 

[A] The actual dates for the 2000 period are August 7 through October 
31, 2000 to coincide with the $250 price cap. The 1998 period runs from 
August 1-October 31. We refer to both periods as August through 
October. 

Sources: GAO’s presentation of price data from the California Power 
Exchange and demand data from CAISO. 

[End of figure] 

Figure 3 shows that the hours of highest demand—1 p.m. through 4 p.m.
and 5 p.m. through 8 p.m.—did not correspond to the highest average
price, as would be expected under competitive conditions. Instead, the
highest average prices came in the lower demand hours of—9 a.m. through
12 p.m. and 9 p.m. through 12 a.m. For example, in the highest demand
hours, 1 p.m. through 4 p.m., demand averaged about 33,300 MWh, and the
price averaged about $164 per MWh. In contrast, during the hours, 9 
p.m. through 12 a.m., demand averaged about 27,600 MWhs and price 
averaged about $182 per MWh. 

We discussed the patterns of prices with CAISO staff and reviewed 
studies to try to explain why the prices did not follow the expected 
pattern in August through October 2000. According to CAISO staff, 
during this period, some suppliers increased the proportion of their 
electricity generation that they sold directly to CAISO, as opposed to 
selling in the power exchange as the market design intended. CAISO 
staff explained that, during this period, CAISO purchased some 
electricity at the last minute at prices above the prevailing price cap 
in order to keep demand and supply in balance and avoid blackouts. As a 
result, staff said, in-state suppliers withheld some of their 
electricity from the power exchange market and waited to sell at higher 
prices at the last minute. One recent study of the California 
electricity market concluded that suppliers knew that CAISO was 
unwilling to allow blackouts, even when prices were very high.[Footnote 
9] Therefore, the study concluded, the price cap created a game of 
“chicken” between suppliers and CAISO. Suppliers would wait until the
last minute to sell their electricity, in an attempt to see how much the
increasingly desperate CAISO would pay. The supplier behavior described
by CAISO staff and in studies we reviewed was consistent with the
exercise of market power, because the prices charged did not reflect the
marginal costs of generating additional megawatt-hours of electricity.
Rather, the behavior reflected an ability to charge higher prices by 
waiting to commit the generation to a time when buyers were willing to 
pay more. Other studies we reviewed analyzed the marginal costs of 
generating electricity during this period and concluded that these 
costs were well below the market prices we observed. 

In addition to discussing our findings with CAISO staff and reviewing
other studies, we examined other market data to try to explain the
unexpected pattern of demand and prices observed from August through
October 2000. We found that the supply of electricity was scarcer during
that period than during the baseline period, owing in large part to a
reduction in available imports of electricity from other western states.
While greater scarcity can explain generally higher prices, it does not
explain the pattern of prices we found. Even when electricity becomes 
increasingly scarce, prices should be higher during high-demand periods
than when demand is lower, unless suppliers can, through the exercise of
market power, affect prices in lower-demand periods. Therefore, based on
our analysis and our review of other studies, we believe this pattern of
prices demonstrates that suppliers exercised market power by raising
prices above their marginal cost. Because we did not have specific cost
data and could not accurately measure the role of scarcity in 
determining prices, we were unable to isolate the relative role of 
market power in causing the high prices found during 2000. 

Other Studies also Found Suppliers Exercised Market Power: 

The authors of the other studies discussed in table 1 found that 
suppliers exercised market power by raising prices above marginal costs 
of generating electricity. Although these authors used different
methodologies and studied varying time frames, they all reported that 
the exercise of market power was a key factor contributing to higher 
prices in the California market. The reported effect that market power 
had on prices varied: while the California State Auditor made no 
specific estimate, the authors of the Berkeley/Stanford study 
attributed as much as 51 percent of the price increases in the summer 
of 2000 to market power. The CAISO-B study concluded that $6.2 billion 
in higher electricity prices resulted from the exercise of market power 
by electricity suppliers during May 2000 through February 2001. 
Additional details of these studies are presented in appendix III. 

The authors of the studies reported that other factors besides market
power, such as increased production costs and a tight supply-demand
balance, also contributed to higher electricity prices in California. 
Some of the authors noted that higher production costs contributed to 
higher prices in California during 2000 compared with earlier years. 
These costs included costs to purchase natural gas, which had increased 
in price, and costs of emissions permits required for some generators 
to allow them to operate. Some of the authors reported that tight 
demand and supply balances also affected prices. Demand increased 
because of unusually hot weather, while supply was scarcer because of 
the reduced availability of electricity imports from other states and a 
lack of new electricity generation in California in the preceding 
years. 

Market Design in California Enabled Exercise of Market Power: 

California’s market design enabled wholesale electricity suppliers to
exercise market power. According to prominent experts and analysts, two
principal market design flaws increased suppliers’ ability to raise 
prices above competitive levels: (1) retail prices were frozen, and (2) 
with few exceptions, the Public Utilities Commission limited utilities’ 
ability to enter into long-term contracts with suppliers. In addition, 
we found that California’s market design lacked effective price 
mitigation strategies to be used once exercise of market power was 
suspected. 

A provision of California’s restructuring legislation froze retail 
prices for consumers for 4 years or until the utilities recovered 
certain costs incurred under the prior regulated market.[Footnote 10] 
Numerous authors of studies of the California electricity market, 
including those studies discussed previously in this report and others, 
noted that the retail price freeze meant that consumers in California 
did not reduce their use of electricity when prices began to rise in 
May 2000.[Footnote 11] Economists and other market design experts 
commonly recognized that such insensitivity to price changes is a key
factor that enables suppliers to raise prices above competitive levels 
under tight supply conditions.[Footnote 12] Therefore, the frozen 
retail prices in California created a situation in which suppliers 
could charge high prices during some periods without worrying that 
consumers would reduce their use of electricity. 

With few exceptions, the California Public Utilities Commission severely
limited the utilities’ use of long-term contracts until after 
electricity prices increased in the summer of 2000.[Footnote 13] The 
Congressional Budget Office notes that in California, as much as 50 
percent of electricity purchases occurred immediately before 
electricity was needed to meet demand, compared to 10 to 20 percent in 
other states that had restructured their electricity markets.[Footnote 
14] Economists and other market design experts recognize that when 
suppliers have signed long-term contracts to sell much of their 
capacity at pre-determined prices, they have a much smaller incentive 
and ability to exercise market power. For example, authors of a study 
of the June 2000 price increases in California concluded that if the 
utilities had signed long-term contracts for their expected demand for 
the months of May and June 2000, average prices in the power exchange 
would have been significantly lower.[Footnote 15] FERC also reported in 
November 2000 that flawed market rules—especially frozen retail prices 
and limited long-term contracts—contributed to unusually high prices in 
the summer of 2000 in California.[Footnote 16] These studies and others 
concluded that the absence of such contracts between California’s 
utilities and wholesale suppliers created conditions under which these 
suppliers could and would exercise market power. 

In the course of our analysis, we found that the CAISO’s use of price 
caps was ineffective in mitigating high prices and bringing them down to
competitive levels in 2000. Other studies and expert opinion also
concluded that these price caps did not work, in part because they only
applied to the state of California—when prices in surrounding states 
were higher than the CAISO’s price cap, wholesale suppliers naturally 
tried to sell to the highest location, which led to problems getting 
needed electricity into California. 

Our statistical analysis indicates that the CAISO price caps were
ineffective in bringing prices down; in fact, when they lowered the 
price cap from $750 to $500 per MWh and again to $250, average prices 
rose.[Footnote 17] Specifically, prices during May and June—when the 
$750 price cap was in place—averaged about $93 per MWh. During the 
period in which the $500 cap was in place—July1 through August 6—prices 
rose, averaging about $143 per MWh. When the price cap was lowered 
again to $250, prices again rose, averaging about $164 per MWh from 
August 7 through October 31. Our analysis does not allow us to say 
whether the price caps caused the increase in average prices, or if so, 
explain why that happened, but it is clear that they were not effective 
in bringing prices down to competitive levels. 

We reviewed studies and interviewed experts to try to determine why the
price caps were not effective. There was general agreement that one 
major flaw in the design of the price caps was that they did not apply 
to the entire western region. As one expert put it, “California is part 
of a larger western electricity market, and as a result, the CAISO 
price cap created an incentive for suppliers to sell electricity 
outside of California whenever prices were higher in surrounding 
states.” Another study concluded that the implementation of the price 
cap was also flawed. The author of the study noted that the CAISO did 
not commit to keeping a firm price cap, because it was unwilling to 
impose blackouts on customers even when prices increased a great deal. 
As a result, the author said, the CAISO was put in a very weak position 
when it came to negotiating prices for electricity at the last minute 
and suppliers were able to drive up prices above the cap level. 

The CAISO told us that as part of the design of California’s 
restructured electricity market, the CAISO had limited authority to 
mitigate high prices when it found they were caused by the exercise of 
market power. This authority was largely limited to imposing prices 
caps on what the CAISO would be willing to pay for electricity from in-
state suppliers. These caps did not apply to electricity purchased from 
out-of-state suppliers. Moreover, if prices outside the state rose 
above the California price cap, then in-state suppliers would have an 
incentive to export electricity, thereby making electricity scarcer and 
placing a greater burden on the CAISO to purchase more electricity at 
the last minute to balance demand and supply, sometimes at prices above 
the price cap. As a result, capping prices in the state was ineffective 
in bringing down the total expenditures on electricity. 

FERC also implemented a mitigation plan in December 2000. FERC’s
mitigation plan reduced the price cap from $250 to $150, but allowed
sellers to receive higher prices for their electricity if they could 
justify the higher prices by demonstrating that their costs of 
generating or acquiring the electricity were higher than $150 per MWh. 
As mentioned previously in this report, prices remained relatively high 
throughout the winter of 2000 and 2001 despite FERC’s mitigation 
efforts.[Footnote 18] While it would appear that FERC’s December 
mitigation plan was not effective in bringing prices down to 
competitive levels, there were other confounding changes in the market 
environment, including sharp increases in natural gas prices and
increasing financial difficulties of the state’s three largest 
utilities, that make it difficult to isolate the impact of FERC’s 
actions on prices. Therefore, we were unable to evaluate the 
effectiveness of FERC’s mitigation strategy. 

Conclusion: 

As discussed in this report, a number of factors caused electricity 
prices to rise in California in the summer of 2000 and at other times 
since restructuring. Based on our analysis and studies by prominent 
economists and other market analysts, the exercise of market power by 
wholesale suppliers was clearly one of those factors explaining the 
high prices. Further, the design of the California electricity market 
created almost textbook conditions under which market power would be 
expected to exist. As a result, electricity suppliers could withhold 
electricity from the market until it was critically needed, and at that 
time, could raise prices above competitive levels. Attempts by the 
CAISO to mitigate the resulting high prices during 2000 were 
unsuccessful due to inadequacies in design and implementation of the 
mitigation strategies. This experience in California highlights the 
importance of properly designing competitive electricity markets and 
the need for effective mitigation when restructured markets do not 
perform as expected. 

Objectives, Scope, and Methodology: 

To determine whether wholesale suppliers of electricity exercised market
power, we examined and analyzed market data on generation, demand,
and prices of electricity in California from April 1998 through October
2000. We did not analyze the period after October 2000 because there 
were many changes to the market, that beginning in November 2000 made it
difficult to determine what competitive prices should be. Among these
changes were sharp increases in natural gas prices, increasing financial
difficulties for the state’s two largest utilities, and the eventual 
closure of the power exchange. The data we used came from the 
California Power Exchange, CAISO, and California Energy Commission. We 
performed statistical analyses to determine whether there were changes 
in the pattern of prices across different levels of demand during the 
summer and early fall of 2000. We also assessed other possible 
explanations for the high electricity prices experienced during 2000, 
including increased scarcity of supply, higher than normal demand, 
natural gas fuel costs faced by sellers, and the reduced availability 
of imports of electricity from other states. Appendix I contains a 
complete discussion of our methodology and analysis. In addition, we 
evaluated numerous other studies to determine what other analysts had 
concluded about the existence and extent of market power in the 
California electricity market. In particular, we focused on five 
studies that covered a range of time periods and methodological 
approaches and that addressed directly at least one of our objectives. 
A full bibliography of the studies we reviewed is contained in appendix 
IV. We did not have sufficient data to evaluate whether individual 
companies exercised market power, or to determine how much of the high 
prices experienced in California was the result of market power versus 
other factors that may have led to tighter demand and supply balances 
or to higher costs of generating electricity during this period. 

To determine what role, if any, the design of California’s market 
played in facilitating suppliers’ ability to exercise market power, we 
evaluated the CAISO’s price mitigation efforts. Specifically, we 
performed a statistical analysis of the relationship between prices and 
levels of demand, controlling for the various price caps imposed by the 
CAISO. We compared the periods in 2000—during which the CAISO lowered 
its price caps twice, and prices were generally high—with previous 
periods in 1998 and 1999, during which prices were generally lower. We 
also reviewed numerous studies by academics, industry analysts, and 
government agencies. Further, we interviewed academics, industry 
experts, industry participants, and officials from state and federal 
government, including the CAISO, California Energy Commission, 
Electricity Oversight Board of California, California Public Utility 
Commission, and FERC. In addition, where applicable, we applied 
established economic concepts and theories to predict the likely 
effects of the CAISO’s market power mitigation plan on prices and the 
supply of electricity. 

We evaluated as well, FERC’s market power mitigation plan, implemented
in December 2000. Data limitations precluded us from evaluating the
effectiveness of the FERC plan, but we reviewed academic studies that
discussed FERC’s mitigation methodology. 

We conducted our work from July 2001 through May 2002 in accordance
with generally accepted government auditing standards. 

As arranged with your offices, unless you publicly announce its contents
earlier, we plan no further distribution of this report until 30 days 
after the date of this letter. At that time, we will send copies to 
appropriate congressional committees, the Federal Energy Regulatory 
Agency, the Director of the Office of Management and Budget, and other 
interested parties. We will make copies available to others on request. 

If you or your staff have any questions about this report, please 
contact me at (202) 512-3841. Key contributors to this report are 
listed in appendix V. 

Signed by: 

Jim Wells: 
Director, Natural Resources and Environment: 

[End of section] 

Appendix I: Determining the Existence of Market Power and Impact of 
CAISO Price Caps: 

This appendix provides a detailed discussion of the analysis we used to
determine whether market power existed in California’s electricity 
market in 2000 and also to estimate the impact of the CAISO’s changes 
to price caps in July and August 2000. We conducted econometric 
analyses using data on market prices in the forward electricity market 
operated by the California Power Exchange and demand data from the 
California Independent System Operator (CAISO). We also evaluated data 
on imports, reserve electricity purchases, and other purchases at the 
last minute by the CAISO to balance demand and supply. 

In summary, the results of our econometric analysis are inconsistent 
with the absence of market power and are not fully explained by other 
factors, such as increased scarcity of supply or increases in costs of 
generating electricity. Therefore, we have concluded that market power 
played a role in the high prices experienced in California in 2000. 
Because we do not have sufficient data to allow us to measure costs or 
scarcity with precision, we could not estimate the extent to which the 
high prices were attributable to these factors versus market power on 
the part of wholesale suppliers. 

We also found that the price caps imposed by the CAISO in an effort to
mitigate market power were ineffective in reducing average prices. In
particular, we found that when price caps were reduced in the summer of
2000—from $750 per MWh down to $500 on July 1 and from $500 to $250
on August 7—average prices actually rose. Other studies and experts we
interviewed pointed out flaws in the design and implementation of these
price caps that likely caused them to be ineffective. In addition to 
our own analysis, we interviewed economists and other industry experts 
to get their views on our methodology and results. Our findings are 
consistent with other studies by academics, industry experts, and staff 
of the CAISO. 

Methodology for Evaluating Electricity Prices: 

To determine whether the high wholesale electricity prices in summer
2000 were consistent with expected behavior in the absence of market
power, we developed an econometric model to estimate the relationship
between prices in the power exchange market and variables expected to
influence the price, such as the quantity supplied, time of day, and 
price cap regulation. In this model, we estimated a regression in which 
the quantity supplied is divided into two parts: the part that is 
served by instate generation, and the part served by imports. In 
general, greater quantity supplied is predicted to lead to higher 
prices. However, in discussions with experts on the California 
electricity market, we were told that the availability of imports has a 
large impact on prices in the state. In particular, imports have a 
damping effect on prices, because costs of generating electricity are 
lower in surrounding states than in California. In addition, they said 
that the highest cost suppliers during most hours are instate 
generators, and it is these suppliers that set the market price for
California. Therefore, we expect to find a negative relationship between
imports and price and a positive relationship between in-state 
generation and price. 

The model included dummy variables for periods of time during which the
CAISO had imposed price caps.[Footnote 19] We expected price cap 
variables to have a negative or insignificant impact on prices based on 
the theory of supply and demand. We also included dummy variables for 
different years, months, days of the week, and hours of the day, to 
account for unobserved variations in demand and costs over time. 
Finally, we included squared and cubed in-state generation terms to 
account for a possible non-linear relationship between price and 
quantity supplied of in-state generation.[Footnote 20] 

The final form of our regression is shown in the following equation. 

[Refer to PDF for equation] 

In the equation, price is the hourly price set in the power exchange 
market in an auction held one day ahead of when the electricity will be 
generated and consumed. “Gen” refers to in-state generation in MWhs, and
“net imports” is the amount of electricity imported, minus the amount
exported, also in MWhs. “Pcaps” is a vector of dummy variables for
various price caps that existed in California between April 1, 1998, 
and the end of our analysis, October 31, 2000.[Footnote 21] “Time 
periods” is a vector of dummy variables for year, month, day of the 
week, and hour of the day. 

The results of the ordinary least squares regression are shown in table 
2. 

Table 2: Price Regression Results: 

Explanatory variables[A]: Constant; 
Coefficient estimate: 51.42918; 
Standard error: 4.800264[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: In-state generation ;
Coefficient estimate: 0.0019569; 
Standard error: 0.0006479[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: (In-state generation)2; 
Coefficient estimate: -4.14E-07; 
Standard error: 3.91E-08[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: (In-state generation)3; 
Coefficient estimate: 1.26E-11; 
Standard error: 6.69E-13[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: Net imports; 
Coefficient estimate: -0.0056135; 
Standard error: 0.0002955[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 250 Price Cap (1998-1999); 
Coefficient estimate: 0.2356245; 
Standard error: 2.067501. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 750 Price cap; 
Coefficient estimate: 6.352422; 
Standard error: 3.738449[D]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 500 Price cap; 
Coefficient estimate: 56.09492; 
Standard error: 4.93126[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 250 Price cap (2000); 
Coefficient estimate: 72.7612; 
Standard error: 5.241998[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 1999; 
Coefficient estimate: 19.03923; 
Standard error: 1.802957[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 2000; 
Coefficient estimate: 33.93763; 
Standard error: 3.739452[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: February; 
Coefficient estimate: -5.197752; 
Standard error: 1.957393[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: March; 
Coefficient estimate: -7.083489; 
Standard error: 1.936569[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: April; 
Coefficient estimate: 1.394583; 
Standard error: 1.8194. 

Explanatory variables[A]: May;
Coefficient estimate: -1.832361; 
Standard error: 1.864067. 

Explanatory variables[A]: June; 
Coefficient estimate: 8.310609; 
Standard error: 2.029737[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: July; 
Coefficient estimate: -14.03577; 
Standard error: 2.206409[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: August; 
Coefficient estimate: 3.875315; 
Standard error: 2.309641[D]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: September; 
Coefficient estimate: 22.55745; 
Standard error: 2.192674[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: October; 
Coefficient estimate: 25.19806; 
Standard error: 2.469456[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: November; 
Coefficient estimate: 22.89343; 
Standard error: 2.670744[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: December; 
Coefficient estimate: 18.10554; 
Standard error: 2.6692[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: Sunday; 
Coefficient estimate: -9.019749; 
Standard error: 1.392289[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: Monday; 
Coefficient estimate: -1.399346. 
Standard error: 1.299002. 

Explanatory variables[A]: Tuesday; 
Coefficient estimate: -1.486778; 
Standard error: 1.295473. 

Explanatory variables[A]: Thursday; 
Coefficient estimate: -5.967485; 
Standard error: 1.295307[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: Friday; 
Coefficient estimate: -8.301758; 
Standard error: 1.298334[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: Saturday; 
Coefficient estimate: -8.434973; 
Standard error: 1.356632[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 2 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: -4.364651; 
Standard error: 2.41029[D]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 3 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: -5.185202; 
Standard error: 2.440988[C]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 4 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: -7.350066; 
Standard error: 2.473241[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 5 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: -6.126103; 
Standard error: 2.496086[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 6 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: -0.0317145; 
Standard error: 2.497901. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 7 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 7.907819; 
Standard error: 2.480037[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 8 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 17.78537; 
Standard error: 2.454051[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 9 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 18.97172; 
Standard error: 2.428454[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 10 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 22.8728; 
Standard error: 2.417118[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 11 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 26.67939; 
Standard error: 2.423078[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 12 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 27.99686; 
Standard error: 2.431365[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 1 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 20.62724; 
Standard error: 2.438165[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 2 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 27.76876; 
Standard error: 2.443315[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 3 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 28.13216; 
Standard error: 2.44639. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 4 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 24.37271; 
Standard error: 2.449033[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 5 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 20.00959; 
Standard error: 2.45096[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 6 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 15.99276; 
Standard error: 2.458588[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 7 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 14.57276; 
Standard error: 2.467717[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 8 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 10.16211; 
Standard error: 2.472744[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 9 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 17.10398; 
Standard error: 2.481656[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 10 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 15.11537; 
Standard error: 2.46666[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 11 p.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 6.660357; 
Standard error: 2.437887[B]. 

Explanatory variables[A]: 12 a.m. 
Coefficient estimate: 1.924638; 
Standard error: 2.409756. 

Notes: Adjusted R-square: 0.4983. 

[A] The dependent variable is price. 

[B] Significance at the 1-percent level. 

[C] Significance at the 5-percent level. 

[D] Significance at the 10-percent level. 

[End of table] 

The regression estimates indicate a positive relationship between price
and in-state generation, and a negative relationship between price and 
net imports as expected. The relationship appears to be somewhat non-
linear, although the non-linear terms are small in magnitude. The 
initial price cap of $250 per MWh, which was in place from July 18, 
1998, through September 30, 1999, had no significant impact on prices. 
In addition, the $750 price cap appeared to have only a weak if any 
impact on price. However, lowering the price caps from $750 to $500 per 
MWh and again from $500 to $250 was associated with increases in 
average prices. This result is inconsistent with what would be expected 
under normal conditions, where a price cap can only cause prices to 
fall and then only during periods where the cap is lower than the 
market price. 

In addition to the least-squares regression results reported, we also
performed various checks for robustness. First, we calculated standard
errors for the regression coefficient estimates that are robust to
heteroscedasticity (White, 1980)[Footnote 22], and to serial 
correlation and heteroscedasticity (Newey and West, 1987).[Footnote 23] 
The statistical results did not qualitatively change from the reported 
regression in that lowering the price caps from $750 to $500 per MWh, 
and then from $500 to $250, resulted each time in a statistically 
significant increase in the market clearing price. 

Second, because the residuals of the least-squares regression indicated
first-order serial correlation, we estimated the regression controlling 
for the serial correlation and obtained qualitatively similar results 
using both least-squares standard errors and robust (White, 1980) 
standard errors. 

Third, we analyzed the impact of extreme observations on the regression
results because, in least-squares models, the expected value of the 
market-clearing price and large deviations from the mean can 
disproportionately affect the coefficient estimates. We estimated a 
bounded influence regression (Kraskel, Kuh, and Welsch, 1983)[Footnote 
24] in which extreme outlying observations are down weighted; the 
results of this regression were similar to the least-squares regression 
although the $250 price cap had a much larger positive effect on the 
market price. We also estimated a quantile regression in which the 
median of the market price was modeled because the median is not 
sensitive to extreme outliers (see Judge et al., 1985, ch. 20); 
[Footnote 25] the results of the median regression were similar to the 
least-squares regression results, although the magnitude of the $250 
price cap was again larger. 

On balance, the regression results indicate that when price caps were
lowered in 2000, average prices rose—a result that is potentially
inconsistent with competitive conditions but which does not directly
indicate the existence of market power. Average prices could have risen
due to changes in some other factors that influenced electricity prices 
and coincided with the lowering of the price caps, but that are not 
accounted for in the regression model. For example, the increase in 
prices could have been caused by increases in costs that coincided with 
the lowering of the price caps.[Footnote 26] To determine whether there 
was evidence of market power, we had to explore other possible 
explanations for the unexpected regression results. 

Determining the Existence of Evidence of Market Power: 

In order to explore the possibility that market power was being 
exercised, we focused our attention on the period from July 1, 2000—the 
day the $500 price cap was implemented—through October 31—the last date 
of our regression analysis. This period encompassed the date the $250 
per MWh price cap was implemented—August 7, 2000. As discussed in this
report, prices did not follow the pattern expected under competitive
conditions during the period of the $250 price cap. In an attempt to
explore other possible explanations for the observed pattern of prices, 
we compared two periods—the first from July 1 through August 6, 2000,
during which the price cap was set at $500 per MWh, and the second from
August 7 through October 31, 2000, during which the cap was $250. In
particular, we evaluated the increase in average prices and the change 
in the pattern of prices that occurred when the price cap was lowered 
from $500 to $250 per MWh. Figure 4 shows prices and total electricity 
demand in the two periods in which the price caps were $500 and $250 
per MWh, respectively. While lowering the price cap was associated with 
falling prices in the two highest demand periods, it was also 
associated with rising prices in all other periods. 

Figure 4: Demand and Prices: 

[Refer to PDF for image] 

This figure is a combination multiple vertical bar and multiple line 
graph. The vertical bars depict electricity demand (in thousands of 
MWhs) at a $500 price cap and at a $250 price cap during the following 
hours of the day: 
1-4 A.M.
5-8 A.M. 
9 A.M. -12 P.M. 
1-4 P.M. 
5-8 P.M. 
9 P.M.-12 A.M. 

Lines on the graph depict prices (in dollars per MWh) with a $500 price 
cap and a $250 price cap during the same hours of the day. Demand 
peaked during the 1-4 P.M. hours in both price caps. Price cap $500 
peaked during the 1-4 P.M. hours and price cap $250 peaked during the 9 
P.M.-12 A.M. hours. 

Source: GAO analysis of CAISO and California Power Exchange data. 

[End of figure] 

As discussed in this report, the increased prices in the lower-demand
periods are not consistent with competitive pricing if all other 
factors are held constant. However, we cannot conclude directly from 
this pattern that market power was the cause of the increases in prices 
or changes in the pattern of prices. Therefore, we evaluated numerous 
variables, including imports of electricity from surrounding states, 
last-minute purchases of electricity to balance demand and supply by 
the CAISO, prices of natural gas (the principle fuel used by many of 
the in-state generators), total demand, and total in-state generation. 
We found that these variables were all changing over time, but in ways 
that should have led to lower rather than higher prices or were of 
insufficient magnitude to explain the price increase. 

For example, imports and net-imports (imports minus exports) of
electricity into California were higher during low- and high-demand 
hours in the $250-price-cap period than in the $500-price-cap period. 
Our regression results indicate that higher levels of net imports are 
associated with lower prices. Therefore, changes in net imports are 
unlikely to explain the increase in prices during low-demand hours 
after the price cap was lowered to $250 per MWh. In addition, levels of 
in-state generation are also lower during low- and high-demand hours in 
the $250-price-cap period than when the cap was $500 per MWh. Our 
regression results indicate that lower levels of in-state generation 
are associated with lower prices. Therefore, levels of in-state 
generation are unlikely to account for the increases and change in 
pattern of prices after the cap was lowered to $250 per MWh. Similarly, 
total demand was lower during low- and high-demand hours in the $250-
price-cap period. As discussed in this report, lower levels of total 
demand are predicted to be associated with lower prices. Therefore 
levels of total demand cannot account for the observed price changes. 

Last-minute purchases of electricity to balance the system were 
relatively unchanged over the two periods. In particular, purchases of 
regulation electricity, spinning reserves, and non-spinning reserves 
were close in both low- and high-demand hours in the two periods. 
[Footnote 27] 

Among the variables affecting electricity prices was the price of 
natural gas, which rose over this period. While this increase would be 
expected to cause electricity prices to rise under competitive 
conditions, prices would likely rise in proportion to the change in 
natural gas prices. However, electricity prices during low-demand hours 
rose by much more, proportionally, than did average natural gas prices, 
which means that gas prices are not likely to fully explain the 
increase in prices during these hours. 

In addition to evaluating these variables, we discussed our findings 
with two economists with electricity market expertise. They agreed that 
the pattern of prices we observed was not consistent with competitive
conditions. In particular, they said that the fact that prices rose so 
much at the lowest levels of demand indicates that suppliers changed 
their behavior in response to the price cap. Both also agreed that the 
price cap caused some suppliers to avoid the capped prices, either by 
withholding some of their electricity from the power exchange and 
offering it directly to the CAISO at the last minute and at higher 
prices or by selling it in surrounding states, where prices were at 
times higher than $250. Further, they said that this withholding of 
power from the capped market would likely have caused other suppliers 
to increase their asking price for electricity, knowing that they faced 
less competition. The economists said that such a change in behavior is 
only consistent with the existence of market power, because suppliers 
who do not have market power treat prices as given and do not take 
actions designed to achieve a higher price. 

We also discussed this period of time with staff of the CAISO. In
discussions with the CAISO, we were told that sellers were able to
partially avoid the price cap by selling some of their power outside the
state—perhaps to an affiliated company—and then buying it back to sell 
to the CAISO at the last minute when the CAISO was desperate to balance
demand and supply and therefore willing to pay prices above the capped
rate. 

We did not have data on specific transactions between suppliers and
buyers outside of the capped market, and we had no data on out of state
sales or prices. Therefore, we could not verify that supplier behavior
changed in the ways suggested by the economists we interviewed and
CAISO staff. However, we were able to look at aggregate levels of 
exports of electricity from California to surrounding states. We found 
that monthly exports were significantly higher from May through October 
2000, than they had been in these same months in 1998 or 1999. 
Specifically, monthly exports from May through October 2000 were 
between about 40 and 230 percent higher than the same months in 1998 or 
1999. Overall, exports were about 200 percent higher from May through 
October 2000 than in the same period in either 1998 or 1999. 

In balance, the combination of the results of our econometric analysis, 
our analysis of prices and other variables in the period surrounding 
the change in the price cap from $500 to $250 per MWh, and the 
interpretation of the economists and CAISO staff we interviewed provide 
evidence that suppliers were able to exercise market power during the 
period after the $250 price cap was implemented. 

Determining the Effectiveness of Price Caps on Market Power Mitigation: 

The results of our regression indicated that average prices rose when 
the caps were lowered during summer 2000. This pattern was inconsistent
with our expectations about the impact of price caps. To explain these
inconsistent results, we reviewed other studies and interviewed 
economists and other experts. There was broad agreement that flaws in
the design and implementation of the price caps led to their being
ineffective as tools for mitigating market power. 

The flaws in design identified by studies and experts relate to the 
ability of suppliers to avoid the price caps and sell at prices above 
the cap. In particular, the cap was imposed by the CAISO to limit what 
CAISO would pay for power in the last-minute markets. However, 
California is a part of a larger western regional market, and the CAISO 
cap did not apply to other states. Therefore, when prices in other 
states rose above the CAISO price cap, suppliers in California had an 
incentive to sell their electricity to other states. As a result, the 
CAISO found that it was forced to buy a larger share of the total 
electricity consumed in a given hour during the last minutes before it 
was needed to meet demand. CAISO was also faced at times with paying 
prices higher than the cap to avoid electricity shortages and forced
blackouts for some consumers. According to one study, the inability of 
the CAISO to commit to maintaining the cap, even at the risk of 
blackouts, gave suppliers a bargaining advantage in setting their 
prices for sales to the CAISO at the last minute. 

[End of section] 

Appendix II: Key Events during Electricity Restructuring in California: 

September 23, 1996: Governor signs Assembly Bill 1890 Implementing 
restructuring in California, creating the Power Exchange and CAISO. 

April 1, 1998: Restructured market opens. 

July 18, 1998: FERC allows the CAISO to set price caps on some market 
sales at $250 per megawatt-hour. 

January 27, 1999: FERC confirms the CAISO's authority to reject bids to 
sell power that exceed the price caps in effect. 

July 1999: San Diego Gas and Electric Company have recovered costs and 
will be allowed to charge market rates to retail customers. 

September 30, 1999: The CAISO raises its price cap for electricity 
sales to $750 per megawatt-hour effective October 1, 1999. 

March 16, 2000: The California Public Utilities Commission authorizes, 
with restrictions, Pacific Gas and Electric Company and Southern 
California Edison to increase their ability to enter into forward 
contracts. 

April 26, 2000: The CAISO price cap of $750 per megawatt-hour is 
reached for the first time. 

May 2000: During this month and throughout the summer of 2000, 
customers of San Diego Gas and Electric Company receive bills that are 
double or triple their average rates. 

May 22,	2000: The first of many Stage 2 alerts, which indicate power 
reserves are less than 5 percent, is declared by the CAISO. 

June 14, 2000: Rolling power blackouts affect the San Francisco area, 
with a loss of power to hundreds of thousands of customers. 

July 1,	2000: The CAISO lowers its price cap to $500 per megawatt-hour 
for electricity sales. 

August 7, 2000: The CAISO lowers its price cap to $250 per megawatt-
hour for power sales. 

September 6, 2000: The governor signs legislation re-imposing a retail 
rate freeze of 6.5 cents per kilowatt-hour for some customers of San 
Diego Gas and Electric. The rate freeze is retroactive to June 1, 2000. 

December 15, 2000: FERC implements a soft cap of $150 per megawatt-hour 
on electricity sales in California, but suppliers can charge the 
utilities more if a higher rate is justified. 

January 11, 2001: A stage 3 alert, where power reserves will fall below 
1 and 1/2 percent within the next two hours, is declared by the ISO. 
This is the first of 32 straight days of Stage 3 warnings, which 
included rolling blackouts on many of those days. 

January 17, 2001: The California Department of Water Resources starts 
buying some electric power on behalf of the three major investor-owned 
utilities. 

January 30, 2001: Electricity sales are suspended at the power 
exchange, which closes permanently the next day. 

February 1, 2001: The governor signs legislation giving the state 
authority to sign long-term contracts for electricity. 

March 7, 2001: The governor authorizes state agencies to expedite the 
siting for various types of power plants. 

March 9, 2001: The power exchange files for bankruptcy. FERC order 
refunds to California from 13 suppliers for sales made to the Power 
Exchange and CAISO. 

March 27, 2001: The California Public Utilities Commission approves a 
rate increase of approximately 40 percent for customers of Pacific Gas 
and Electric Company and Southern California Edison. This is the 
highest rate increase in California history. 

April 6, 2001: Pacific Gas and Electric Company files for bankruptcy. 

April 25, 2001: FERC issues an order establishing price controls within 
California, whenever the CAISO issues stage 1, 2 or 3 power alert. The 
plan is to take effect within 15 days and expire after one year. 

May 10,	2001: The Governor signs legislation authorizing up to $13.4 
billion in revenue bonds to finance power purchases. 

May 16,	2001: The Governor signs legislation creating the California 
Consumer Power and Conservation Financing Authority, which is 
authorized to build, own and operate new electricity and transmission 
facilities. 

June 18, 2001: FERC expands price mitigation plan to cover entire 11 
western state region for spot electricity sales, 24 hours a day, 7 days 
a week. Caps were to be tied to costs of generating electricity for the 
highest cost generating unit required to meet demand. 

September 20, 2001: The California Public Utilities Commission suspends 
the direct access program for consumers basically eliminating consumer 
choice on the selection of retail electricity providers. 

December 19, 2001: FERC raises the price cap for western region sales 
of electricity to $108 per megawatt-hour for spot transactions outside 
the CAISO control area. 

April 23, 2002: California renegotiates terms for 5 long-term 
electricity contracts. 

May 1, 2002: CAISO submits market redesign proposal for controlling 
energy prices and meeting demand to FERC for review and approval. 

Sources: Multiple news stories, public documents, and studies. 

[End of section] 

Appendix III: Summary of Studies on Market Power: 

Borenstein, Severin, James Bushnell, and Frank Wolak. “Measuring Market 
Inefficiencies in California’s Restructured Wholesale Electricity 
Market.” (unpublished). February 2002: 

The authors examined the degree of competition in the California
electricity market from June 1998 to October 2000. They compared market
prices, using pricing data from the power exchange, with estimates of
marginal costs of producing additional electricity. The authors tested
whether the overall market was setting competitive prices considering 
the production capabilities of all suppliers in the market. The analysis
included such cost factors as fuel costs; maintenance costs; and costs 
for emissions control, a regulatory requirement for some geographic
locations. Adjustments were not made for costs related to inefficient
transmission of power between geographic areas. Using the cost data, the
authors computed the perfectly competitive price for each hour for the
months in the sample period. The authors then categorized higher
expenditure for wholesale purchases of electricity during the summer of
2000 into increases in production cost, scarcity, and the exercise of 
market power. The authors found that 51 percent of total electricity 
expenditures in the summer of 2000 could be attributed to market power. 
They note that market power was most commonly exercised during peak 
demand periods. 

Joskow, Paul, and Edward Kahn. “A Quantitative Analysis of Pricing 
Behavior in California’s Wholesale’s Electricity Market During the 
Summer 2000: The Final Word.” (unpublished). February 4, 2002: 

The authors simulated competitive prices under various demand and
supply conditions that existed during the summer of 2000. They then used
public data on production on an hourly basis from EPA and other public
sources and compared the actual prices from this data with their
estimated competitive wholesale benchmark prices. The benchmark price
was the short-run cost of supplying electricity from the last unit that 
would clear the market in each hour. Factors such as fuel prices and 
costs for emissions control to meet environmental requirements were 
included in the analysis. These authors found that wholesale prices far 
exceeded competitive levels during the months of June through September 
2000. They noted that evidence supports the conclusion that power was
withheld from the market by electricity suppliers, which contributed to 
the high prices during the summer of 2000. 

Hildebrant, Eric. Further Analyses of the Exercise and Cost Impacts of
Market Power in California’s Wholesale Energy Market. A special study 
by the Department of Market Analysis, California Independent System 
Operator, Folsom, California, March, 2001: 

This CAISO economist evaluated electricity prices in California for the
period of April 1998 through February 2001. This study compared the
difference between actual wholesale prices in the CAISO system with an
estimate of baseline costs that would be incurred under competitive
market conditions. He included in this analysis the potential impacts of
emissions costs and price impacts from hours when supply was scarce.
The results of the analysis showed that market power was being exercised
for the period evaluated, between May 2000 and February 2001. The author
estimated that overall wholesale costs during that period had been 
driven up by more than $6.2 billion by the exercise of market power and 
that over 30 percent of wholesale electricity costs during the year 
prior to his study could be attributed to market power. 

Sheffrin, Anjali. Empirical Evidence of Strategic Bidding in California 
ISO Real Time Market. A special study by the Department of Market 
Analysis, California Independent System Operator, Folsom, California, 
March 21, 2001: 

This CAISO economist reviewed bids from five large in-state non-investor
owned utility suppliers, as well as 16 importers selling electricity in 
the real-time market of the CAISO for each hour between May and November
2000. She compared detailed bidding data in the real-time market to the
marginal cost of supplying energy and analyzed the level of mark-up for
each supplier. The author used real-time data from the CAISO market for
specific companies and generation units. She found bidding behavior that
was not consistent with competitive bidding. Further, she found that
wholesale suppliers displayed forms of physical and/or economic
withholding of electricity for the purposes of inflating prices. The 
author concluded that large suppliers were actively engaged in bidding 
behavior that had a direct impact on market prices, and she noted that 
this behavior indicated systematic exercise of market power to maximize 
profits. 

California State Auditor. Energy Deregulation: The Benefits of 
Competition Were Undermined by Structural Flaws in the Market, 
Unsuccessful Oversight, and Uncontrollable Competitive Forces. 
Sacramento, California, March 22, 2001: 

The California State Auditor reviewed the operations of the power
exchange and CAISO, including prices in the electricity market for the
period April 1998 through December 2000. Consultants for the State
Auditor reviewed reports and statistical and econometric models used by
various monitoring, and/or market analysis groups of the power exchange
and CAISO. They also interviewed respective members of these 
organizations. The State Auditor concluded that market participants
adopted tactics to manipulate wholesale electricity prices in 
California. The authors noted that bidding data from the last year 
prior to the March 2001 issuance of their report suggested that both 
buyers and sellers deliberately attempted to manipulate electricity 
prices. Market participants utilized bidding strategies that held back 
needed supply, which then forced the CAISO to make purchases at 
exorbitant prices to guarantee system reliability. 

[End of section] 

Appendix IV: Bibliography of Selected Studies: 

United States General Accounting Office, Restructured Electricity
Markets: Three States’ Experiences in Adding Generating Capacity.
[hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-02-427]. Washington, D.C.: 
May 24, 2002. 

Stoft, Steven. “Power System Economics: Designing Markets for
Electricity.” IEEE/Wiley, 2002. 

McCullough, Robert. “Revisiting Market Power After Two Years.” Public
Utilities Fortnightly, April 1, 2002. 

Joskow, Paul, and Edward Kahn. “A Quantitative Analysis of Pricing
Behavior in California’s Wholesale’s Electricity Market During the 
Summer 2000: The Final Word.” (unpublished). February 4, 2002. 

Borenstein, Severin, James Bushnell and Frank Wolak. “Measuring Market
Inefficiencies in California’s Restructured Wholesale Electricity 
Market.” (unpublished). February 2002. 

Borenstein, Severin. “The Trouble With Electricity Markets: 
Understanding California’s Restructuring Disaster.” Journal of Economic 
Perspectives, Volume 16, Number 1, (Winter 2002): pages 191-211. 

California Independent System Operator, Department of Market Analysis.
Third Annual Report on Market Issues and Performance, Market 
Monitoring, Investigative, and Compliance Activities, January-
December 2001. Folsom, California, January 2002. 

Harvey, Scott, M. and William W. Hogan. “Identifying the Exercise of
Market Power in California.” (unpublished). December 28, 2001. 

Harvey, Scott, M. and William Hogan. “Market Power and Withholding.”
(unpublished). December 20, 2001. 

California State Auditor. California Energy Markets, Pressures Have
Eased but Cost Risks Remain. Sacramento, California, December 2001. 

Harvey, Scott, M., and William Hogan. “Further Analysis of the Exercise 
of Market Power in the California Electricity Market.” (unpublished).
November 21, 2001. 

Morey, Matthew, J. Ensuring Sufficient Generating Capacity, During the
Transition to Competitive Electricity Markets. prepared for Edison
Electric Institute, Washington, D.C.: November 2001. 

Borenstein, Severin, James Bushnell, Christopher R. Knittel, and 
Catherine Wofram. “Trading Inefficiencies in California’s Electricity 
Markets.” (unpublished). October 2001. 

California Independent System Operator, Department of Market Analysis.
Second Annual Report on Market Issues and Performance. April 1999-
December 2000. Folsom, California: November 2001. 

Wolak, Frank A. “Designing a Competitive Electricity Market that 
Benefits Consumers.” (unpublished). October 15, 2001. 

Joskow, Paul L. “California’s Electricity Crisis” (unpublished). 
September 28, 2001. 

Congressional Budget Office. Causes and Lessons of the California
Electricity Crisis. Washington, D.C., September 2001. 

California Energy Commission. California Energy Outlook, Electricity
and Natural Gas Trends Report. Staff Draft, Sacramento, California,
September 2001. 

Hirst, Eric. “The California Electricity Crisis: Lessons for Other 
States.” (unpublished). July 10, 2001. 

Joskow, Paul and Edward Kahn. “Identifying the Exercise of Market
Power: Refining the Estimates.” (unpublished). July 5, 2001. 

Taylor, Jerry, and Peter VanDoren. “California’s Electricity Crisis 
What’s Going On, Who’s to Blame, and What to Do.” Policy Analysis, No. 
406, (July 3, 2001). 

United States General Accounting Office. Energy Markets: Results of
Studies Assessing High Electricity Prices in California. [hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-01-857]. Washington, D.C.: June 29, 
2001. 

United States General Accounting Office. California Electricity Market:
Outlook for Summer 2001. [hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-01-870R]. Washington, D.C.: June 29, 
2001. 

United States General Accounting Office. California Electricity Market
Options for 2001: Military Generation and Private Backup Possibilities.
[hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-01-865R]. Washington, D.C.: 
June 29, 2001. 

Electric Power Research Institute. The Western States Power Crisis:
Imperatives and Opportunities, an EPRI White Paper. Palo Alto,
California, June 25, 2001. 

Department of Market Analysis, California Independent System Operator.
Potential Overpayments Due to Market Power in California’s Wholesale
Energy Market: May 2000-2001. Folsom, California: June 19, 2001. 

Rowe, John W., Peter Thornton, and Janet Bieniak Szcypinski. 
Competition Without Chaos. Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Working
Paper 01-07, June 2001. 

Hogan, William W. Electricity Market Restructuring: Reforms of Reforms.
Paper presented at annual conference of Center for Research in Regulated
Industries, Rutgers University: May 23-25, 2001. 

Harvey, Scott M. “On the Exercise of Market Power Through Strategic
Withholding in California.” (unpublished). April 24, 2001. 

Hildebrandt, Eric. Impacts of Market Power in California’s Wholesale
Energy Market: More Detailed Analysis Based on Individual Seller
Schedules and Transactions in the ISO and PX Markets. A special study
by the Department of Market Analysis, California Independent System
Operator, Folsom, California, April 9, 2001. 

Sheffrin, Anjali. Empirical Evidence of Strategic Bidding in California
ISO Real Time Market. A special study by the Department of Market
Analysis, California Independent System Operator, Folsom, California:
March 21, 2001. 

Harvey, Hal, Bentham Paulos and Eric Heitz. California and the Energy
Crisis: Diagnosis and Cure. Energy Foundation, March 8, 2001. 

Hildebrant, Eric. Further Analyses of the Exercise and Cost Impacts of
Market Power in California’s Wholesale Energy Market. A special study
by the Department of Market Analysis, California Independent System
Operator, Folsom, California: March, 2001. 

Edison Electric Institute. Learning from California: Power Shortages and
Unique Market Rules Lead to Price Spikes. Washington, D.C.: March 2001. 

California State Auditor. Energy Deregulation: The Benefits of 
Competition Were Undermined by Structural Flaws in the Market, 
Unsuccessful Oversight, and Uncontrollable Competitive Forces.
Sacramento, California: March 22, 2001. 

California Independent System Operator, Department of Market Analysis.
Report on Real Time Supply Costs above Single Price Auction Threshold:
December 8, 2000-January 31, 2001. Folsom, California: February 28, 
2001. 

Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Office of the General Counsel,
Market Oversight and Enforcement and Office of Markets, Tariffs and
Rates, Division of Energy Markets. Report on Plant Outages in the State
of California. Washington, D.C.: February 1, 2001. 

Joskow, Paul and Edward Kahn. “A Quantitative Analysis of Pricing
Behavior in California’s Wholesale Electricity Market During Summer
2000.” (unpublished). January 2001. 

Borenstein, Severin. “The Trouble With Electricity Markets (and some
solutions). (unpublished). January, 2001. 

Chandley, John, D., Scott M. Harvey, and William W. Hogan. “Electricity
Reform in California.” (unpublished). November 22, 2000. 

Federal Energy Regulator Commission. Staff Report on Western Markets
and the Causes of the Summer 2000 Price Abnormalities: Part I of the
Staff Report on U.S. Bulk Power Markets. Washington, D.C.: November 1,
2000. 

Puller, Steven L. “Pricing and Firm Conduct in California’s Deregulated
Electricity Market”. (unpublished). November 2000. 

Marcus, William and Jan Hamrin. “How We Got Into the California Energy
Crisis.” (unpublished). November 2000. 

Harvey, Scott, M. and William W. Hogan. “Issues in the Analysis of 
Market Power in California.” (unpublished). October 27, 2000. 

Barker, Dunn and Rossi, Inc. “The Electric Summer: Symptoms-Options-
Solutions.” A special report prepared for Edison Electric Institute,
October 2000. 

Nordhaus, Robert, Frank A. Wolak, and Carl Shapiro. An Analysis of the
June 2000 Price Spikes in the California ISO’s Energy and Ancillary
Services Market. A special report prepared for the Market Suveillance 
Committee of the California Independent System Operator, September 6,
2000. 

California Independent System Operator, Department of Market Analysis.
Report on California Energy Market Issues and Performance: May-June
2000, Special Report. Folsom, California: August 10, 2000. 

California Public Utilities Commission and Electricity Oversight Board.
Summer 2000 Report for Governor Davis Regarding California’s 
Electricity System. San Francisco, California, August 2, 2000. 

Borenstein, Severin, James Bushnell, and Frank Wolak. “Diagnosing
Market Power in California’s Restructured Wholesale Electricity Market.”
(unpublished). August 2000. 

Borenstein, Severin, and James Bushnell. “Electricity Restructuring:
Deregulation or Reregulation?” (unpublished). February 2000. 

Bushnell, James, B. and Frank A. Wolak. “Regulation and the Leverage of
Local Market Power in the California Electricity Market.” (unpublished).
September 1999. 

Borenstein, Severin. “Understanding Competitive Pricing and Market
Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets” (unpublished). August 1999. 

Borenstein, Severin, James Bushnell, and Christopher R. Knittel. “Market
Power in Electricity Markets: Beyond Concentration Measures.”
(unpublished). February 1999. 

Tirole, Jean. The Theory of Industrial Organization. The MIT Press, 
1988. 

[End of section] 

Appendix V: GAO Contacts and Staff Acknowledgments: 

GAO Contacts: 

Jim Wells (202) 512-3841: 
Dan Haas (202) 512-9828: 

Acknowledgments: 

In addition to those named above, Art James, Randy Jones, Jon
Ludwigson, Cynthia Norris, and Frank Rusco made key contributions to
this report. 

[End of section] 

Footnotes: 

[1] The three utilities are Pacific Gas & Electric, Southern California 
Edison, and San Diego Gas & Electric. 

[2] One megawatt-hour is enough electricity to serve the needs of 750 
typical homes for an hour. 

[3] Overall prices are an average of prices paid in the power exchange 
markets and prices paid by the CAISO for last-minute purchases. 

[4] U.S. General Accounting Office, Energy Markets: Results of Studies 
Assessing High Electricity Prices in California, [hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-01-857] (Washington, D.C.: June 29, 
2001). 

[5] U.S. General Accounting Office, California Electricity Market 
Options for 2001: Military Generation and Private Backup Possibilities, 
[hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-01-865R] (Washington, D.C.: 
June 29, 2001). 

[6] The FERC price cap is actually linked to costs of generating 
electricity. If costs rise or fall, the cap will also rise or fall. 

[7] U.S. General Accounting Office, Restructured Electricity Markets: 
Three State’s Experiences in Adding Generating Capacity, GAO-02-427 
(Washington, D.C.: May 24, 2002). 

[8] We chose these two periods after conducting a statistical analysis 
of price and demand data from April 1, 1998, through October 31, 2000. 
This analysis indicated that the August through October 2000 period 
differed significantly from similar months in 1998 and 1999, when 
prices were relatively low. Therefore, we focused further on this 
period and compared it to the same months in 1998. 

[9] Borenstein, Severin, “The Trouble With Electricity Markets: 
Understanding California’s Restructuring Disaster,” Journal of Economic 
Perspectives, Volume 16, Number 1, Winter (2002): pages 191-211. 

[10] The retail price freeze was in effect for Pacific Gas & Electric 
Company and Southern California Edison for the entire 4-year period. 
San Diego Gas and Electric Company recovered its costs in 1999 and 
started charging consumers their full costs. When prices rose in spring 
and summer 2000, California enacted legislation in September 2000 to 
again freeze consumer prices for most customers of San Diego Gas and 
Electric Company. 

[11] See appendix IV for a complete bibliography of studies we 
reviewed. 

[12] For a discussion of the relationship between price sensitivity and 
the ability of suppliers to exercise market power, see Jean Tirole, The 
Theory of Industrial Organization, The MIT Press, 1988. 

[13] Even after the restrictions on long-term contracts were relaxed, 
the Public Utilities Commission would not guarantee that utilities 
could recover what they paid for electricity purchased in long-term 
contracts. Officials of one of the three main utilities told us that, 
without such a guarantee, they believed the risk of signing long-term 
contracts was too great. 

[14] Congressional Budget Office, Causes and Lessons of the California 
Electricity Crisis, Washington, D.C., September 2001. 

[15] Frank A. Wolak, Robert Nordhaus, and Carl Shapiro, An Analysis of 
the June 2000 Price Spikes in California ISO’s Energy and Ancillary 
Services Markets, a special report for the Market Surveillance 
Committee of the California Independent System Operator, September 6, 
2000. 

[16] Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Staff Report to the Federal 
Energy Regulatory Commission on Western Markets and the Causes of the 
Summer 2000 Price Abnormalities (Washington, D.C., Nov. 1, 2000). 

[17] Our analysis focuses on prices in the power exchange market and 
therefore does not address the prices CAISO paid for electricity in 
last minute purchases. Price caps may have affected the prices paid by 
the CAISO, but we did not have sufficient data to analyze this. 
Nonetheless, the majority of electricity purchases during the period we 
analyzed were made in the power exchange. 

[18] In June 2001, FERC revised and expanded its mitigation plan, 
lowering the price cap again and extending its scope to encompass all 
western states. Subsequently, prices fell dramatically. As discussed 
previously, FERC’s region-wide price cap has been partially credited by 
some for causing prices to fall. Other factors that may have led to 
lower prices were cooler weather, increases in supply, conservation 
efforts, and the state’s long-term electricity contracts with wholesale 
suppliers. 

[19] A dummy variable takes a value of 1 if a certain characteristic is 
present and a value of 0 otherwise. 

[20] It is important to note that we are not estimating either a demand 
or supply relationship. 

[21] The price data are hourly market clearing prices from the power 
exchange day-ahead market. Other variables are hourly data from the 
CAISO. 

[22] White, H. “A heteroscedasticity-consistent covariance matrix 
estimator and a direct test for heteroscedasticity.” Econometrica, 48, 
1980, 817-838. 

[23] Newey, W. and K. West. “A simple positive semi-definite, 
heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix.” 
Econometrica, 55, 1987, 703-708. 

[24] Krasker, W. S., S. E. Kuh, and R. E. Welsch. “Estimation for dirty 
data and flawed models.” in Z. Griliches and M. D. Intriligator (eds.) 
Handbook of Econometrics, vol 1, Amsterdam, North Holland, 1983, 652-
698. 

[25] Judge, G.G., and W. E. Griffiths, R. C. Hill, H. Lutkepohl, and T. 
C. Lee. The Theory and Practice of Econometrics. New York, Wiley, 2nd 
Edition, 1985. 

[26] Another possibility is that there were increases in prices of 
electricity in surrounding states that coincided with the lowering of 
price caps in California. In this case, in-state suppliers would be 
able to get higher prices in surrounding states, and this would cause
prices in California to rise as well. 

[27] Regulation electricity, spinning reserves and non-spinning 
reserves are purchased by the CAISO to balance demand and supply and 
maintain enough reserves of supply to keep the system operating 
reliably as demand and supply conditions change. 

[End of section] 

GAO’s Mission: 

The General Accounting Office, the investigative arm of Congress, 
exists to support Congress in meeting its constitutional 
responsibilities and to help improve the performance and accountability 
of the federal government for the American people. GAO examines the use 
of public funds; evaluates federal programs and policies; and provides 
analyses, recommendations, and other assistance to help Congress make 
informed oversight, policy, and funding decisions. GAO’s commitment to 
good government is reflected in its core values of accountability, 
integrity, and reliability. 

Obtaining Copies of GAO Reports and Testimony: 

The fastest and easiest way to obtain copies of GAO documents at no 
cost is through the Internet. GAO’s Web site [hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov] contains abstracts and full text files of current 
reports and testimony and an expanding archive of older products. The 
Web site features a search engine to help you locate documents using 
key words and phrases. You can print these documents in their entirety, 
including charts and other graphics. 

Each day, GAO issues a list of newly released reports, testimony, and 
correspondence. GAO posts this list, known as “Today’s Reports,” on its 
Web site daily. The list contains links to the full-text document 
files. To have GAO e-mail this list to you every afternoon, go to 
[hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov] and select “Subscribe to daily E-mail 
alert for newly released products” under the GAO Reports heading. 

Order by Mail or Phone: 

The first copy of each printed report is free. Additional copies are $2 
each. A check or money order should be made out to the Superintendent 
of Documents. GAO also accepts VISA and Mastercard. Orders for 100 or 
more copies mailed to a single address are discounted 25 percent. 

Orders should be sent to: 

U.S. General Accounting Office: 
441 G Street NW, Room LM: 
Washington, D.C. 20548: 

To order by Phone: 
Voice: (202) 512-6000: 
TDD: (202) 512-2537: 
Fax: (202) 512-6061: 

To Report Fraud, Waste, and Abuse in Federal Programs Contact: 

Web site: [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/fraudnet/fraudnet.htm]: 

E-mail: fraudnet@gao.gov: 

Automated answering system: (800) 424-5454 or (202) 512-7470: 

Public Affairs: 
Jeff Nelligan, managing director, NelliganJ@gao.gov: 
(202) 512-4800: 
U.S. General Accounting Office: 
441 G Street NW, Room 7149:
Washington, D.C. 20548: