This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-05-193SP 
entitled 'Social Security Answers to Key Questions' which was released 
on May 19, 2005. 

This text file was formatted by the U.S. Government Accountability 
Office (GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part 
of a longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every 
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of 
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text 
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the 
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided 
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed 
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic 
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail 
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this 
document to Webmaster@gao.gov. 

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work 
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the 
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this 
material separately. 

United States Government Accountability Office: 

Social Security Answers to Key Questions: 

GAO-05-193SP: 

May 2005: 

Contents: 

Preface: 

I. Basically, How Does Social Security Work Now? 

1. How did Social Security get started? 

2. What are Social Security's goals? 

3. How well has Social Security worked? 

Figure 1: Poverty Rates for Elderly Have Declined Faster than for Other 
Groups: 

4. What are the sources of income for the elderly? 

Figure 2: Elderly Households' Sources of Income, 2002: 

Figure 3: Percentage of Elderly Households Receiving Each Type of 
Income, 2002: 

5. Who gets benefits? 

6. What benefits does Social Security offer? 

Figure 4: Benefit Formula Provides Higher Replacement Rates for Lower 
Earners: 

7. When can people get benefits? 

Table 1: Full Retirement Age is Increasing: 

8. How much interest do workers' contributions earn? 

9. What is social insurance? 

10. Where do Social Security's revenues come from? 

11. How much is the Social Security payroll tax? 

12. Why is there a cap on taxable earnings? 

13. What interest rate do the Social Security trust funds earn? 

14. Why are Social Security benefits taxed? 

15. What does "pay-as-you-go financing" mean? 

16. How do the Social Security trust funds relate to the federal 
budget? 

Table 2: Fiscal Year 2004 Deficit Numbers: 

Figure 5: Surplus or Deficit as a Share of GDP, Fiscal Years 1980-2004: 

17. Do Social Security taxes get spent on other government programs? 

18. Aren't the Social Security trust funds like private sector trust 
funds? 

II. Why Is There A Need For Social Security Reform? 

1. What is the basic problem? 

Figure 6: Social Security's Costs Will Exceed its Cash Revenues 
Beginning in 2017: 

2. What are the root causes of this gap between costs and revenues? 

Figure 7: The Aged Are Growing as a Share of the Total Population: 

Figure 8: Labor Force Growth Is Expected to be Negligible by 2050: 

Figure 9: Social Security Workers per Beneficiary: 

3. When does the money run out? 

Figure 10: Social Security's Trust Fund Balance Grows but then Declines 
Rapidly after 2027: 

4. How big is the funding gap in dollars? 

5. Which horizon should we be looking at: 75 years or an infinite 
horizon? 

6. Are there any issues other than solvency that call for reform? 

7. When Social Security's benefit payments exceed its income, where 
will the money come from? 

8. What is the outlook for the whole federal budget and its capacity to 
pay benefits, especially when Medicare and Medicaid are included? 

Figure 11: Federal Spending for Mandatory and Discretionary Programs, 
Fiscal Years 1964, 1984, and 2004: 

Figure 12: Composition of Spending as a Share of GDP, Assuming 
Discretionary Spending Grows with GDP After 2004 and All Expiring Tax 
Provisions Are Extended: 

9. What are the implications of this budgetary outlook for the economy 
as a whole? 

Figure 13: Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid Spending as a 
Percentage of GDP: 

Figure 14: Annual Personal Saving Rates, 1960 - 2004: 

10. Why can't we wait for a more immediate solvency crisis to reform 
Social Security? 

Figure 15: Size of Action Needed to Achieve Social Security Solvency: 

11. But what happens if we don't do anything? 

12. How should we evaluate the various options for Social Security 
reform? 

13. Why do we hear claims about the effects of proposals that directly 
contradict each other? 

14. What benchmarks should be used for comparison? 

III. What Are The Options For Social Security Reform? 

1. What are ways of changing the benefit formula? 

Figure 16: Social Security Benefit Formula Replaces Earnings at 
Different Rates: 

2. How could COLAs be reduced? 

3. How would increasing the retirement age work? 

4. What are the options for increasing tax revenues? 

5. Are there other ways to increase Social Security's revenues? 

6. Who would manage the accounts? 

7. Would accounts be required for Social Security participants? 

8. How much would go into the accounts? 

9. What's the difference between an add-on and a carve-out account? 

10. What are transition costs? 

11. What investment options would there be? 

12. How would participants draw on the accounts for retirement income? 

13. Would participants have any guarantee of doing better than under 
the current system? 

IV. What Are The Implications Of Social Security Reform? 

1. What will achieving sustainable solvency require? 

2. What effects do these options have on the overall federal budget and 
the public debt? 

3. Can Social Security reforms promote economic growth and worker 
productivity? 

4. How would benefit reductions affect the adequacy of benefits? 

5. Does greater progressivity in benefits imply greater income 
adequacy? 

6. What would happen to the adequacy of benefits for the disabled, 
dependents, and survivors? 

7. How will individual equity be affected by these reform options? 

8. What issues would arise in implementing these options? 

9. Would individual accounts help achieve solvency? 

10. What would it cost to create a system with individual accounts? 

11. Aren't these transition costs less than the cost of fixing the 
current system? 

12. What effect would individual accounts have on national saving? 

13. How would individual accounts affect the adequacy of benefits? 

14. What effect would individual accounts have on the adequacy of 
benefits for the disabled, dependents, and survivors? 

15. What issues would arise in implementing individual accounts? 

16. What would happen to administrative costs with individual accounts? 

17. What tools and educational efforts would workers need to exercise 
the increased choices associated with individual accounts? 

V. Glossary Of Key Terms: 

VI. Related Gao Products: 

[End of contents]

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. However, because 
this work may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission 
from the copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce 
this material separately. 

ERRATA: 

On May 18, 2005, this document was revised as follows: text was revised 
on pages 7, 21, and 42; numerical changes were made in table 2 on page 
16; and revisions were made to Figure 1 on page 4, Figure 4 on page 9, 
Figure 5 on page 17, and Figure 11 on page 28. In addition, revisions 
were made to Figure 12 on page 29 and Figure 13 on page 30 to correct 
color-related problems that occurred only in the printed version. 

Preface: 

The sooner our nation acts to address Social Security's long-term 
financial challenges, the easier it will be to successfully meet them. 
Once explained, the choices we face are not difficult to understand, 
but they are difficult to make. They affect both how much Americans pay 
for Social Security and how much they receive from the program. They 
require changes that not only will affect us but have implications for 
future generations. They also are difficult because they involve deeply 
felt values, such as community, individualism, fairness, and human 
dignity. This guide tries to boil down the complexities of Social 
Security and the implications of reform to the basic choices we face as 
a nation. 

Social Security eventually provides benefits to tens of millions of 
Americans: workers and the families of workers who become disabled or 
die, as well as to those who retire. Those benefits are designed to 
replace some of the earnings that such workers lose, but not all of 
them. Social Security was never intended to guarantee an adequate 
income. Also, they are available only to workers, and their families, 
who have contributed to the system. 

People are living longer than ever before, and they are expected to 
live even longer in the future. If workers keep retiring at the same 
age as they do now, they will collect retirement benefits for more 
years than past workers did. If the level of those benefits relative to 
wages stays the same, then lifetime benefits would cost more simply 
because those lifetimes are longer. So this longer life expectancy 
presents workers with a basic choice: How much of their earnings should 
they spend during their peak employment years, and how much should they 
save for retirement? Yet, workers also have other options. They can 
choose to work longer and have more total earnings to spread over their 
lifetimes; they can also choose to invest their savings in ways that 
earn higher returns, but to do so they have to take more risk. 

With or without Social Security, workers face these basic choices as 
they plan for longer lives. The choices we collectively face for Social 
Security are very similar for the very same reasons. And with Social 
Security, the choices will affect not only the program and its 
beneficiaries but also the federal budget and the national economy. 

This guide provides answers to questions about the most basic aspects 
of Social Security and reform issues in a concise and easy-to- 
understand format. We provide straightforward answers to how Social 
Security works, why it needs reform, what the basic options are, and 
how to assess their implications. For readers interested in a deeper 
and more detailed discussion, we include a bibliography of related GAO 
products. A glossary defining key terms is included at the back of this 
document. 

This report was prepared under the direction of Barbara D. Bovbjerg, 
Director, Education, Workforce, and Income Security Issues, who may be 
reached at (202) 512-7215. Charlie Jeszeck, Michael Collins, Ken 
Stockbridge, and Derald Seid made key contributions to this 
publication. 

Signed by: 

David M. Walker: 

Comptroller General of the United States: 

U.S. Government Accountability Office: 

Basically, how does Social Security work now? 

SOCIAL SECURITY'S GOALS: 

1. How did Social Security get started? 

When Social Security was enacted, in 1935, the nation was in the midst 
of the Great Depression. About half of the elderly (people age 65 and 
over) depended on others for their livelihood, and roughly one-sixth 
received public charity. Many had lost their savings. Social Security 
was created to help ensure that the future elderly would have adequate 
retirement incomes and would not have to depend on welfare. It would 
provide benefits that workers had earned because of their own 
contributions and those of their employers. In 1939, coverage was 
extended to dependents and survivors. The Disability Insurance (DI) 
program was added in 1956. Officially, Social Security is now called 
the Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance (OASDI) program. 

2. What are Social Security's goals? 

Helping ensure adequate retirement income is a fundamental goal of 
Social Security.[Footnote 1] While Social Security was never intended 
to guarantee an adequate income by itself, it provides an income base 
upon which to build. At the same time, Social Security is intended to 
reduce dependency on welfare, so the system is funded by workers' 
contributions that establish their eligibility to receive benefits. 
Both contributions and benefits are based on earnings. Accordingly, 
another goal of the program is to ensure that benefits bear some 
relationship to contributions. This goal is known as individual 
equity.[Footnote 2] The Social Security program, in effect, balances 
the goal of income adequacy and individual equity. The benefit formula 
seeks to ensure adequacy by providing somewhat higher benefits, 
relative to wages, for lower-income workers than higher-income workers. 
At the same time, the formula also promotes some degree of individual 
equity by ensuring that benefits are somewhat higher for workers with 
higher lifetime earnings. 

3. How well has Social Security worked? 

In 2004, Social Security paid almost $493 billion in benefits to more 
than 47 million people. This currently represents 22 percent of the 
federal budget and 4.3 percent of our nation's gross domestic product 
(GDP).[Footnote 3] Social Security has contributed to reducing poverty 
among the elderly. (See Fig. 1.) Since 1959, poverty rates for the 
elderly have dropped by more than two-thirds, from 35 percent to about 
10 percent in 2003. While poverty rates for the elderly in 1959 were 
higher than for children or for working-age adults (aged 18 to 64), in 
2003 they were lower than for either group. Factors other than Social 
Security, for example, employer-provided pensions have also contributed 
to lower poverty for the elderly. Still, for about half of today's 
elderly, their incomes net of Social Security benefits are below the 
poverty threshold, the level of income needed to maintain a minimal 
standard of living. Nearly two-thirds of the elderly get at least half 
of their income from Social Security. One in five elderly Americans has 
no income other than Social Security. 

Figure 1: Poverty Rates for Elderly Have Declined Faster than for Other 
Groups: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Line graph with three lines with 45 items each. 

Year: 1959: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 27.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 17;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 35.2. 

Year: 1960: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 26.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: Not available;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: Not available. 

Year: 1961: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 25.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: Not available;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: Not available. 

Year: 1962: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 25;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: Not available;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: Not available. 

Year: 1963: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 23.1;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: Not available;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: Not available. 

Year: 1964: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 23;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: Not available;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: Not available. 

Year: 1965: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 21;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: Not available;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: Not available. 

Year: 1966: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 17.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.5;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 28.5. 

Year: 1967: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 16.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 29.5. 

Year: 1968: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 15.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 25. 

Year: 1969: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 14;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 8.7;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 25.3. 

Year: 1970: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 15.1;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 24.6. 

Year: 1971: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 15.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 9.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 21.6. 

Year: 1972: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 15.1;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 8.8;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 18.6. 

Year: 1973: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 14.4;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 8.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 16.3. 

Year: 1974: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 15.4;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 8.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 14.6. 

Year: 1975: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 17.1;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 9.2;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 15.3. 

Year: 1976: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 16;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 15. 

Year: 1977: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 16.2;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 8.8;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 14.1. 

Year: 1978: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 15.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 8.7;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 14. 

Year: 1979: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 16.4;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 8.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 15.2. 

Year: 1980: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 18.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.1;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 15.7. 

Year: 1981: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 20;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 11.1;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 15.3. 

Year: 1982: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 21.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 12;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 14.6. 

Year: 1983: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 22.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 12.4;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 13.8. 

Year: 1984: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 21.5;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 11.7;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 12.4. 

Year: 1985: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 20.7;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 11.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 12.6. 

Year: 1986: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 20.5;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.8;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 12.4. 

Year: 1987: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 20.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 12.5. 

Year: 1988: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 19.5;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.5;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 12. 

Year: 1989: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 19.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.2;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 11.4. 

Year: 1990: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 20.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.7;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 12.2. 

Year: 1991: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 21.8;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 11.4;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 12.4. 

Year: 1992: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 22.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 11.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 12.9. 

Year: 1993: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 22.7;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 12.4;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 12.2. 

Year: 1994: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 21.8;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 11.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 11.7. 

Year: 1995: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 20.8;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 11.4;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 10.5. 

Year: 1996: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 20.5;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 11.4;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 10.8. 

Year: 1997: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 19.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 10.5. 

Year: 1998: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 18.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.5;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 10.5. 

Year: 1999: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 16.9;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.1;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 9.7. 

Year: 2000: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 16.2;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 9.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 9.9. 

Year: 2001: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 16.3;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.1;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 10.1. 

Year: 2002: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 16.7;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 10.4. 

Year: 2003: Poverty Rate for Children Under 18: 17.6;
Poverty Rate for Adults 18-64: 10.8;
Poverty Rate for Adults 65+: 10.2. 

Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census. 

Note: Data for years indicated by dashed lines were not available but 
are available for 1959. 

[End of figure]

Moreover, poverty is higher for some subgroups of the elderly than for 
the elderly as a whole. Women, members of minorities, and persons aged 
75 and older are much more likely to be poor than other elderly 
persons. For example, compared with 10 percent for all elderly persons 
(aged 65 and older) in 2003, poverty rates were 21 percent for all 
elderly women living alone, roughly 22 percent for elderly blacks and 
Hispanics, and about 32 percent for black women 75 and older. Unmarried 
women make up more than 70 percent of poor elderly households, although 
they account for only 45 percent of all elderly households. 

At about 19 percent, poverty rates in 2000 were much higher for 
disabled workers age 16-64 than for the elderly (13.2 percent). Like 
the rates for the elderly, poverty rates for disabled workers are 
higher for women, minorities, unmarried persons, and those living 
alone. Social Security provides an important source of income for the 
disabled. In 1999, disabled workers made up 11 percent of all OASDI 
beneficiaries. As with the elderly, Social Security is a major 
component (38 percent) of family income for disabled worker families. 
Also, 48 percent of disabled worker families get half of their income 
or more from Social Security, as of 1999, while 6 percent have no other 
income. 

4. What are the sources of income for the elderly? 

The four major sources of income for the elderly are Social Security, 
employer pensions, income from saved assets, and earnings. While Social 
Security provides income to 90 percent of elderly households, it 
provides just 39 percent of their total retirement income. (See Figs. 2 
and 3.) Pensions, savings, and earnings provide income to considerably 
fewer households but together provide 58 percent of elderly households' 
total income. They largely determine which households have the highest 
retirement incomes. Less than 3 percent comes from other sources, and 
less than 1 percent comes from public assistance. Medical benefits, 
including Medicare and Medicaid, also help relieve a major cost burden 
on the elderly, especially as health care costs grow much faster than 
inflation. 

Figure 2: Elderly Households' Sources of Income, 2002: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Pie chart with five items. 

Social Security: 39%;
Earnings: 25%;
Pensions: 19%;
Savings: 14%;
Other: 3%. 

Source: Income of the Population 55 or Older, 2002 (Washington, D.C.: 
SSA, Office of Research and Statistics, 2005). 

[End of figure]

Figure 3: Percentage of Elderly Households Receiving Each Type of 
Income, 2002: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Bar chart with four items. 

Social Security;
Percentage of elderly households: 90%. 

Savings;
Percentage of elderly households: 55%. 

Pensions;
Percentage of elderly households: 41%. 

Earnings;
Percentage of elderly households: 22%. 

Source: Income of the Population 55 or Older, 2002 (Washington, D.C.: 
SSA, Office of Research and Statistics, 2005). 

[End of figure]

SOCIAL SECURITY'S BENEFITS: 

5. Who gets benefits? 

Social Security benefits are paid to workers who meet requirements for 
the time they have worked in "covered employment," that is, jobs 
through which they have paid Social Security taxes. Social Security 
covers about 96 percent of all U.S. workers; the vast majority of the 
rest are state, local, and federal government employees.[Footnote 4] 
Typically, workers must contribute for a total of 40 quarters (or ten 
years in total) to qualify, though the requirements are different if 
they become disabled or die. Workers and their dependents generally 
become eligible to collect benefits when the workers reach age 62, 
become disabled, or die. 

Benefits are paid to family members of workers under certain 
circumstances. Spouses and divorced spouses of eligible workers may 
also be eligible at age 62 but can be eligible at younger ages if they 
are disabled, widowed, or caring for eligible children. An eligible 
worker's children under 18 are also eligible, and adult children are 
eligible if they became disabled before age 22. Dependent parents and 
grandchildren of eligible workers are also eligible for survivors 
benefits under certain circumstances. 

Some workers qualify for Social Security benefits from both their own 
work and their spouses'. Such workers are called dually entitled 
spouses. Such workers do not receive both the benefits earned as a 
worker and the full spousal benefit; rather the worker receives the 
higher amount of the two. 

6. What benefits does Social Security offer? 

Social Security benefits are designed to partially replace earnings 
that workers lose when they retire, become disabled, or die. As a 
result, the first step of the benefit formula calculates a worker's 
average, indexed monthly earnings (AIME), which is based on the highest 
35 years' earnings on which they paid Social Security taxes. The 
formula adjusts these lifetime earnings, or indexes them to changes in 
average wages, to account for the fact that earnings across all workers 
grow over time. 

Then, the benefit formula replaces a percentage of those pre-retirement 
earnings, replacing a larger share of earnings for lower earners than 
for higher earners. For example, retired workers receive benefits that 
equal about 50 percent of pre-retirement earnings for a worker with 
relatively lower earnings (45 percent of the average wage) but only 
about 30 percent of earnings for one with relatively higher earnings 
(160 percent of the average wage). To help ensure that beneficiaries 
have adequate incomes, Social Security's benefit formula is designed to 
be progressive, that is, to provide disproportionately larger benefits, 
as a percentage of earnings, to lower earners than to higher 
earners.[Footnote 5]

Figure 4: Benefit Formula Provides Higher Replacement Rates for Lower 
Earners: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Bar chart with three items. 

Low steady earner;
Percentage replacement rate at age 65: 49%. 

Average steady earner;
Percentage replacement rate at age 65: 37%. 

High steady earner;
Percentage replacement rate at age 65: 30%. 

Note: Replacement rates are the annual retired worker benefits at age 
65 for workers born in 1985 divided by the earnings in the previous 
year. For such workers, the full retirement age will be 67. Steady 
earners have earnings equal to a constant percentage of Social 
Security's Average Wage Index in every year of their careers. Those 
percentages are 45, 100, and 160, respectively, for low, average, and 
high earners. Benefits for disabled workers use the same formula, but 
since workers become disabled at different ages, it is more difficult 
to calculate a consistent replacement rate. See GAO, Social Security: 
Distribution of Benefits and Taxes Relative to Earnings Level, GAO-04- 
747 (Washington, D.C.: June 15, 2004) for more on replacement rates. 

[End of figure]

Finally, the benefit formula makes other adjustments to reflect various 
other provisions, such as those relating to early or delayed 
retirement, type of beneficiary, and maximum family benefit amounts. In 
addition, once payments have begun, Social Security benefits are 
adjusted annually to reflect inflation. 

7. When can people get benefits? 

For retired workers and their dependents, Social Security pays full 
benefits at the full retirement age, also known as the normal 
retirement age (NRA), which historically has been age 65. However, 
under current law, the full retirement age is gradually increasing, 
beginning with retirees born in 1938, and will reach 67 for those born 
in 1960 or later. (See table 1.) People may choose to retire at age 62 
and receive reduced benefits.[Footnote 6] The reduction for early 
retirement takes account of the longer period of time over which 
benefits will be paid. 

Table 1: Full Retirement Age is Increasing: 

Year of birth: 1937 or earlier;
Full retirement age: 65. 

Year of birth: 1938;
Full retirement age: 65 and 2 months. 

Year of birth: 1939;
Full retirement age: 65 and 4 months. 

Year of birth: 1940;
Full retirement age: 65 and;
Full retirement age: 6 months. 

Year of birth: 1941;
Full retirement age: 65 and 8 months. 

Year of birth: 1942;
Full retirement age: 65 and 10 months. 

Year of birth: 1943-1954;
Full retirement age: 66. 

Year of birth: 1955;
Full retirement age: 66 and 2 months. 

Year of birth: 1956;
Full retirement age: 66 and 4 months. 

Year of birth: 1957;
Full retirement age: 66 and 6 months. 

Year of birth: 1958;
Full retirement age: 66 and 8 months. 

Year of birth: 1959;
Full retirement age: 66 and 10 months. 

Year of birth: 1960 and later;
Full retirement age: 67. 

Source: SSA. 

[End of table]

For disabled workers and their dependents, Social Security pays 
benefits for workers who are unable to work in any job and whose 
disabilities are expected to last for at least 1 year or to result in 
death. Social Security does not pay benefits for short-term or partial 
disability. Also, benefits do not begin until a worker has been 
disabled for 5 full consecutive months. 

For survivors of deceased workers, Social Security pays benefits upon 
the death of the worker for those who satisfy the relevant age 
requirements. For example, a widow can start receiving benefits as 
early as age 60 or, if she is disabled, age 50. 

8. How much interest do workers' contributions earn? 

Workers do not earn interest on their Social Security contributions as 
they would on a savings account. Their contributions are not deposited 
in interest-bearing accounts for individual workers. Rather, their 
contributions are credited to the Social Security trust funds, which 
are primarily used to pay current benefits. Any contributions not used 
for current benefits are invested in interest-bearing federal 
government securities that are not readily marketable but backed by the 
full faith and credit of the U.S. government. The benefit payments paid 
to any given individual are derived from a formula that does not use 
interest rates or the amount of contributions but rather uses the 
individual's average indexed lifetime earnings as a basis for 
determining benefits. 

In technical terms, Social Security provides a defined-benefit pension, 
not a defined-contribution pension. A defined-benefit pension generally 
provides a periodic benefit based on a specific formula generally 
linked to each worker's earnings and years of employment. In contrast, 
a defined-contribution pension resembles an individual savings or 
investment account; retirement income from this type of pension depends 
on the total amount of contributions to the account and any investment 
earnings. As an example, 401(k) accounts are a type of defined- 
contribution pension. 

The benefits workers receive under Social Security do, however, reflect 
a rate of return that they implicitly receive on their 
contributions.[Footnote 7] This implicit rate equals the interest rate 
that workers would hypothetically have to earn on their contributions 
to pay exactly for all the benefits they and their families will 
receive over the course of their lives. This implicit rate of return 
provides one measure of individual equity, that is, the relationship 
between contributions and benefits. It is important to recognize that 
this implicit rate of return individuals receive on their contributions 
is not the same as the interest that the Social Security trust funds 
earn on their assets. Implicit rates of return for individuals depend 
on the relationship between lifetime benefits and contributions, while 
the interest earned by the trust funds reflects the prevailing rates of 
interest in the market. 

Implicit rates of return that individual workers receive on their 
Social Security contributions vary significantly across a number of 
dimensions. The variations mostly reflect several types of income 
transfers that the program is designed to provide as part of its social 
insurance function. Implicit returns vary by birth year, reflecting the 
program's income transfers to the first generations of retirees from 
subsequent generations.[Footnote 8] For example, the inflation- 
adjusted (or "real") implicit rate of return averaged more than 25 
percent annually for the earliest retirees covered by Social Security. 
For the baby boomers (those people born between 1946 and 1964), the 
real implicit rate of return is projected to be around 2 percent, 
according to a Social Security Administration (SSA) study.[Footnote 9] 
Implicit returns that workers receive also vary on average by their 
earnings level, by the number of their dependents and survivors, by 
their life expectancies, and whether they become disabled. These 
characteristics vary by race and gender and therefore the associated 
implicit rates of return do also. 

9. What is social insurance? 

Under a social insurance program, society as a whole insures its 
members against various risks they all face, and members pay for that 
insurance through contributions to the system. Social Security is a 
social insurance program through which the government assumes some of 
the responsibility for a variety of risks that workers face regarding 
their retirement income security. Such risks include individually based 
risks, such as how long they will be able to work, how long they will 
live, whether they will be survived by a spouse or other dependents, 
how much they will earn and save over their lifetimes, and how much 
they will earn on retirement savings. Workers also face some collective 
risks, such as the performance of the economy and the extent of 
inflation. Different types of retirement income embody different ways 
of assigning responsibility for these risks. For example, employers 
sponsoring defined benefit pension plans bear the risk of investing a 
plan's assets and ensuring that contributions are adequate to fund 
promised benefits. In contrast, individuals saving for retirement bear 
that investment risk. 

SOCIAL SECURITY'S REVENUES: 

10. Where do Social Security's revenues come from? 

Social Security's revenues generally come from three sources: 
contributions in the form of payroll taxes, interest on the trust 
funds, and 13 income taxes attributable to Social Security benefits. In 
2004, the shares of total revenue were: 

* 84.1 percent from payroll taxes,

* 13.5 percent from interest on the trust funds, and: 

* 2.4 percent from income taxes on Social Security benefits. 

11. How much is the Social Security payroll tax? 

In 2005, workers pay a payroll tax of 6.2 percent of their covered wage 
earnings up to $90,000 into Social Security, that is, into the OASDI 
trust funds. Their employers pay an equal amount for a combined total 
tax rate of 12.4 percent. Most analysts agree that employees ultimately 
pay the employers' share because employers pay lower wages than they 
would if the employers' contribution did not exist. Self-employed 
workers pay 12.4 percent, but they are allowed an income tax deduction 
for half of the payroll tax. This deduction parallels the favorable tax 
treatment that employers receive on their share of the payroll tax. Of 
the 12.4 percent tax, 1.8 percent is allocated specifically to 
Disability Insurance. The other 10.6 percent is allocated to Old-Age 
and Survivors Insurance. In addition, workers and their employers each 
pay a payroll tax of 1.45 percent of all wage earnings (without any 
cap) into Medicare. 

When Social Security started collecting payroll taxes in 1937, the 
total payroll tax rate was 2 percent. Higher rates were not necessary 
because only a small share of the elderly had contributed enough to the 
program to qualify for benefits. As the system matured--that is, as 
each year passed and another group of people reaching retirement age 
qualified for benefits--benefit costs increased and tax rates 
eventually were increased accordingly. When the program began, payroll 
taxes were anticipated to increase over time with the growth in benefit 
payments as the system matured and more retirees received benefits. 

12. Why is there a cap on taxable earnings? 

The cap on taxable earnings in 2005 is $90,000. This cap is technically 
known as the contribution and benefit base because the same cap also 
effectively limits the earnings that can be used in the benefit 
formula. This in turn limits the size of benefits, reflecting the 
program's role of only providing for a floor of protection. Limiting 
the size of benefits also limits the program's costs and the payroll 
taxes needed to pay for them. 

The cap on taxable earnings has also changed over time. The maximum 
annual earnings subject to the payroll tax were only $3,000 in 1937. 
However, in 1937, 97 percent of all covered workers had total earnings 
below $3,000. In recent years, about 94 percent have had total earnings 
below the taxable maximum. 

13. What interest rate do the Social Security trust funds earn? 

In 2004, the Social Security trust funds earned interest at an 
effective nominal annual rate of 5.7 percent (or 3.1 percent after 
inflation). By law, the Social Security trust fund invests in 
securities backed by the federal government and receives a relatively 
low return that reflects the low level of relative risk. The interest 
rate on special Treasury securities is equal, at the time of issue, to 
the average market yield on outstanding marketable government 
securities not due or redeemable for at least 4 years. This statutory 
rate was intended to confer neither an advantage nor a disadvantage on 
the trust fund but was intended to approximate how much it would cost 
the government to borrow from the public for the long term. 

14. Why are Social Security benefits taxed? 

Since 1984, some Social Security beneficiaries have had to pay federal 
income tax on up to one-half of their Social Security 
benefits.[Footnote 10] These income tax revenues are returned to the 
Social Security trust funds. In 2004, they provided 2 percent of the 
trust funds' total income. [Footnote 11] Currently, about two-thirds of 
Social Security beneficiaries are not affected by the taxation of 
benefits. This tax treatment of Social Security benefits roughly 
parallels the tax treatment of similar defined-benefit pension 
benefits. [Footnote 12] In addition, because of changes in 1993, some 
of these beneficiaries also have to pay federal income taxes on an 
additional 35 percent of their benefits. However, the additional 
revenues collected from this source are dedicated to the Hospital 
Insurance (HI, or Medicare Part A) trust fund and do not increase OASDI 
revenues. 

15. What does "pay-as-you-go financing" mean? 

Social Security is financed largely on a pay-as-you-go basis. In a pay- 
as-you-go system, contributions that workers make in a given year are 
used primarily to pay beneficiaries in that same year. Social Security 
is now temporarily deviating from pure pay-as-you-go financing by 
building up reserves that are by law invested in Treasury bonds. This 
situation has arisen partly because the baby boom generation makes the 
size of the workforce larger relative to the beneficiary population. In 
contrast, in a fully funded, or advance funded, system, contributions 
for a given year are put aside to pay for future benefits. The 
investment earnings on these funds contribute considerable revenues and 
reduce the size of contributions that would otherwise be required to 
pay for the benefits. Defined-contribution pensions and individual 
retirement accounts (IRAs) are fully funded by definition, as the 
benefits received equal the funds accumulated in the account. Also, 
defined-benefit employer pensions are designed with the goal of being 
advance funded: however, at any given point in time total assets may be 
more or less than accrued liabilities and obligations. The pension 
funds accumulate substantial assets that constitute a large share of 
national saving. 

Virtually from the beginning, Social Security was financed on a pay-as- 
you-go basis. Congress had rejected the idea of advance funding for the 
program. Many expressed concern that if the federal government amassed 
huge reserve funds, it would find a way to spend them. Social Security 
has run a surplus (e.g. $151 billion in fiscal 2004). Also, if the 
trust funds were invested in private securities, some people would be 
concerned about the influence that government could have on the private 
sector (e.g. social investing). 

SOCIAL SECURITY AND THE FEDERAL BUDGET: 

16. How do the Social Security trust funds relate to the federal 
budget? 

The Social Security trust funds are sub-accounts within the federal 
accounting and budget systems. Trust funds are budget accounts that are 
16 used to record receipts and expenditures earmarked for specific 
purposes and designated as trust funds by law.[Footnote 13] The 
Department of the Treasury has permanent authority to make Social 
Security benefit payments when there is a fund balance sufficient to 
make those payments. As a result, benefit payments do not require 
annual appropriations from Congress. The trust funds also provide a 
contingency reserve to help ensure that short-term economic downturns 
do not result in funding shortfalls. 

The Social Security trust funds are not included in the measure of the 
federal budget that is known as the "on-budget" deficit. However, the 
trust fund's "off-budget" status does not change the way its year-to- 
year finances contribute to the government's impact on the economy. 
Therefore, Social Security is included, along with all other federal 
programs, in the commonly used unified budget measure. The unified 
budget measures the government's current incremental borrowing from the 
public and related draw on financial markets. Social Security's current 
cash surplus, plus interest earned on treasury securities held by the 
trust funds, partially offsets the deficit in the rest of the 
government's accounts. (See table 2 and Fig. 5.) 

Table 2: Fiscal Year 2004 Deficit Numbers: 

On-budget deficit;
Billions of dollars: ($567);
Percentage of GDP: (4.9%). 

Off-budget surplus;
Billions of dollars: $155[A];
Percentage of GDP: 1.3%. 

Unified deficit;
Billions of dollars: ($412);
Percentage of GDP: (3.6%). 

Source: OMB. 

[A] This includes the $151 billion Social Security surplus and a $4 
billion surplus for the Postal Service. 

[End of table]

Figure 5: Surplus or Deficit as a Share of GDP: Fiscal Years 1980-2004: 

[See PDF for image] - graphic text: 

Line/Stacked Bar combo chart with 1 line (Unified) and 25 bars. 

Fiscal year: 1980;
On-budget: -2.7%;
Off-budget: No data;
Unified: -2.7%. 

Fiscal year: 1981;
On-budget: -2.4%;
Off-budget: -0.2%;
Unified: -2.6%. 

Fiscal year: 1982;
On-budget: -3.7%;
Off-budget: -0.2%;
Unified: -4%. 

Fiscal year: 1983;
On-budget: -6%;
Off-budget: No data;
Unified: -6%. 

Fiscal year: 1984;
On-budget: -4.8%;
Off-budget: No data;
Unified: -4.8%. 

Fiscal year: 1985;
On-budget: -5.3%;
Off-budget: 0.2%;
Unified: -5.1%. 

Fiscal year: 1986;
On-budget: -5.4%;
Off-budget: 0.4%;
Unified: -5%. 

Fiscal year: 1987;
On-budget: -3.6%;
Off-budget: 0.4%;
Unified: -3.2%. 

Fiscal year: 1988;
On-budget: -3.9%;
Off-budget: 0.8%;
Unified: -3.1%. 

Fiscal year: 1989;
On-budget: -3.8%;
Off-budget: 1%;
Unified: -2.8%. 

Fiscal year: 1990;
On-budget: -4.8%;
Off-budget: 1%;
Unified: -3.9%. 

Fiscal year: 1991;
On-budget: -5.4%;
Off-budget: 0.9%;
Unified: -4.5%. 

Fiscal year: 1992;
On-budget: -5.5%;
Off-budget: 0.8%;
Unified: -4.7%. 

Fiscal year: 1993;
On-budget: -4.6%;
Off-budget: 0.7%;
Unified: -3.9%. 

Fiscal year: 1994;
On-budget: -3.7%;
Off-budget: 0.8%;
Unified: -2.9%. 

Fiscal year: 1995;
On-budget: -3.1%;
Off-budget: 0.9%;
Unified: -2.2%. 

Fiscal year: 1996;
On-budget: -2.3%;
Off-budget: 0.9%;
Unified: -1.4%. 

Fiscal year: 1997;
On-budget: -1.3%;
Off-budget: 1%;
Unified: -0.3%. 

Fiscal year: 1998;
On-budget: -0.3%;
Off-budget: 1.1%;
Unified: 0.8%. 

Fiscal year: 1999;
On-budget: No data;
Off-budget: 1.4%;
Unified: 1.4%. 

Fiscal year: 2000;
On-budget: 0.9%;
Off-budget: 1.5%;
Unified: 2.4%. 

Fiscal year: 2001;
On-budget: -0.3%;
Off-budget: 1.6%;
Unified: 1.3%. 

Fiscal year: 2002;
On-budget: -3.1%;
Off-budget: 1.5%;
Unified: -1.5%. 

Fiscal year: 2003;
On-budget: -4.9%;
Off-budget: 1.5%;
Unified: -3.5%. 

Fiscal year: 2004;
On-budget: -4.9%;
Off-budget: 1.3%;
Unified: -3.6%. 

Source: Office of Management and Budget and Congressional Budget 
Office. 

[End of figure]

17. Do Social Security taxes get spent on other government programs? 

Yes. By law, the Social Security trust funds must invest in interest- 
bearing federal government securities.[Footnote 14] Treasury then uses 
the cash to pay for other government expenses. In effect, Treasury uses 
Social Security's excess revenues to help reduce the amount it must 
borrow from the public to finance other federal programs. In other 
words, Social Security's excess revenues help reduce the overall, or 
unified, federal budget deficit. If Treasury could not borrow from the 
trust funds, it would have to borrow more in the private capital market 
and pay such interest in cash to finance current budget policy. 
However, Treasury still has to pay the trust funds interest on these 
securities. When Social Security needs to draw on the trust funds to 
pay benefits, Treasury provides cash in exchange for redeemed trust 
fund securities.[Footnote 15]

18. Aren't the Social Security trust funds like private sector trust 
funds? 

No. Most federal trust funds, including the Social Security trust 
funds, do not have the fiduciary relationships that characterize 
private trust funds. Unlike private trust funds, which are managed 
largely on behalf of the beneficiary, the federal government has much 
more flexibility and latitude. The Office of Management and Budget 
(OMB) summarizes the differences between federal and private trust 
funds as follows: 

"The beneficiary of a private trust owns the trust's income and often 
its assets. A custodian manages the assets on behalf of the beneficiary 
according to the stipulations of the trust, which he cannot change 
unilaterally. In contrast, the Federal Government owns the assets and 
earnings of most Federal trust funds, and it can unilaterally raise or 
lower future trust fund collections and payments, or change the purpose 
for which the collections are used, by changing existing law." 
[Footnote 16]

[SECTION I NOTES]

[1] GAO, Social Security: Program's Role in Helping Ensure Income 
Adequacy, GAO-02-62 (Washington, D.C.: Nov. 30, 2001). 

[2] GAO, Social Security: Issues in Comparing Rates of Return With 
Market Investments, GAO/HEHS-99-110 (Washington, D.C.: Aug. 5, 1999). 

[3] GDP is the value of all goods and services produced within the 
United States in a given year and is conceptually equivalent to incomes 
earned in production. 

[4] About one-fourth of public employees do not pay Social Security 
taxes on the earnings from their government jobs. Historically, Social 
Security did not require coverage of government employees because there 
was concern over the question of the federal government's right to 
impose a tax on state governments and some had their own retirement 
systems. In 1983, Congress extended mandatory coverage to newly hired 
federal workers and to all members of Congress, regardless of when they 
entered Congress. See GAO, Social Security: Issues Relating to 
Noncoverage of Public Employees, GAO-03-710T (Washington, D.C.: May 1, 
2003). 

[5] GAO, Social Security: Distribution of Benefits and Taxes Relative 
to Earnings Level, GAO-04-747 (Washington, D.C.: June 15, 2004). 

[6] Social Security also pays reduced benefits as early as age 62 for 
spouses, and widow(er)s. 

[7] GAO, Social Security: Issues in Comparing Rates of Return With 
Market Investments, GAO/HEHS-99-110 (Washington, D.C.: Aug. 5, 1999). 

[8] While these early beneficiaries may have received a substantial 
income transfer within the Social Security system, as a group they 
contributed substantial amounts outside the system to the retirement 
incomes of their parents' generation, which did not qualify for Social 
Security benefits. Such contributions included not only income support 
that some provided to their own parents but also taxes and charitable 
contributions that paid for other forms of support. 

[9] Dean R. Leimer, Cohort-Specific Measures of Lifetime Net Social 
Security Transfers, working paper 59 (Washington, D.C.: SSA, Office of 
Research and Statistics, Feb. 1994): 

[10] Individual income tax filers pay this tax if their adjusted gross 
income plus tax-exempt interest income plus one-half their Social 
Security benefits exceeds $25,000. A married couple filing jointly will 
pay the tax if this income exceeds $32,000. These levels are not 
adjusted for inflation, so the percentage of beneficiaries paying tax 
on Social security benefits is expected to rise in the future. 

[11] The Social Security trust funds also receive interest income that 
is not subject to tax. In 2004, 14 percent of the trust funds' income 
came from interest on the Social Security trust funds. 

[12] In most defined-contribution pensions, such as 401(k) plans, 
contributions are made from tax-deferred income and participants are 
subject to income taxation on all benefits they receive. 

[13] GAO, Federal Trust and Other Earmarked Funds: Answers to 
Frequently Asked Questions, GAO-01-199SP (Washington, D.C.: Jan. 2001). 

[14] These securities, while unmarketable, are backed by the full faith 
and credit of the U.S. government and guaranteed as to both principal 
and interest. 

[15] For more detail about the temporary trust fund buildup and how it 
interacts with the federal budget, see GAO, Social Security Financing: 
Implications of Government Stock Investing for the Trust Fund, the 
Federal Budget, and the Economy, GAO/AIMD/HEHS-98-74 (Washington, D.C.: 
Apr. 22, 1998), and GAO, Social Security Reform: Demographic Trends 
Underlie Long-Term Financing Shortage, GAO/T-HEHS-98-43 (Washington, 
D.C.: Nov. 20, 1997). 

[16] OMB, Analytical Perspectives, Chapter 17, "Trust Funds and Federal 
Funds" (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, February 1998), 
p. 321. 

[End of Section I]

II. Why is there a need for Social Security Reform? 

SOCIAL SECURITY'S OUTLOOK: 

1. What is the basic problem? 

Social Security's benefit costs will soon start to grow rapidly. In 
2017, Social Security is projected to pay out more cash in benefits 
than it receives in revenues.[Footnote 1] As Figure 6 shows, after that 
time, the gap between costs and income grows continuously, and, unless 
action is taken to close this gap, the trust funds will eventually be 
depleted in 2041. 

Figure 6: Social Security's Costs Will Exceed its Cash Revenues 
Beginning in 2017: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Line graph with two lines and 81 items. 

Calendar year: 2000;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.69;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 10.4. 

Calendar year: 2001;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.71;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 10.56. 

Calendar year: 2002;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.74;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 10.92. 

Calendar year: 2003;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.71;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 11.05. 

Calendar year: 2004;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.75;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 11.15. 

Calendar year: 2005;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.72;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 11.13. 

Calendar year: 2006;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.73;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 11. 

Calendar year: 2007;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.74;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 10.95. 

Calendar year: 2008;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.78;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 10.99. 

Calendar year: 2009;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.77;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 11.13. 

Calendar year: 2010;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.79;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 11.25. 

Calendar year: 2011;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.84;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 11.42. 

Calendar year: 2012;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.87;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 11.67. 

Calendar year: 2013;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.9;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 11.93. 

Calendar year: 2014;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.92;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 12.21. 

Calendar year: 2015;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.94;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 12.49. 

Calendar year: 2016;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.96;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 12.79. 

Calendar year: 2017;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 12.98;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 13.09. 

Calendar year: 2018;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 13.4. 

Calendar year: 2019;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.01;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 13.71. 

Calendar year: 2020;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.03;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 14.03. 

Calendar year: 2021;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.05;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 14.34. 

Calendar year: 2022;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.07;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 14.65. 

Calendar year: 2023;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.09;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 14.95. 

Calendar year: 2024;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.11;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 15.25. 

Calendar year: 2025;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.12;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 15.55. 

Calendar year: 2026;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.14;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 15.83. 

Calendar year: 2027;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.16;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 16.1. 

Calendar year: 2028;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.17;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 16.34. 

Calendar year: 2029;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.19;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 16.55. 

Calendar year: 2030;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.2;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 16.74. 

Calendar year: 2031;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.21;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 16.92. 

Calendar year: 2032;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.22;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.08. 

Calendar year: 2033;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.23;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.2. 

Calendar year: 2034;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.24;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.3. 

Calendar year: 2035;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.24;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.37. 

Calendar year: 2036;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.25;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.44. 

Calendar year: 2037;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.25;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.48. 

Calendar year: 2038;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.26;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.5. 

Calendar year: 2039;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.26;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.51. 

Calendar year: 2040;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.26;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.52. 

Calendar year: 2041;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.26;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.52. 

Calendar year: 2042;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.27;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.53. 

Calendar year: 2043;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.27;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.54. 

Calendar year: 2044;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.27;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.54. 

Calendar year: 2045;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.27;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.55. 

Calendar year: 2046;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.27;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.56. 

Calendar year: 2047;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.27;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.58. 

Calendar year: 2048;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.28;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.6. 

Calendar year: 2049;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.28;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.62. 

Calendar year: 2050;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.28;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.64. 

Calendar year: 2051;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.28;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.68. 

Calendar year: 2052;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.29;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.71. 

Calendar year: 2053;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.29;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.75. 

Calendar year: 2054;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.29;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.8. 

Calendar year: 2055;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.3;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.84. 

Calendar year: 2056;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.3;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.89. 

Calendar year: 2057;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.3;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 17.95. 

Calendar year: 2058;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.31;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18. 

Calendar year: 2059;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.31;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.05. 

Calendar year: 2060;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.31;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.1. 

Calendar year: 2061;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.32;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.16. 

Calendar year: 2062;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.32;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.22. 

Calendar year: 2063;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.32;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.28. 

Calendar year: 2064;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.33;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.34. 

Calendar year: 2065;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.33;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.4. 

Calendar year: 2066;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.34;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.46. 

Calendar year: 2067;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.34;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.52. 

Calendar year: 2068;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.34;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.57. 

Calendar year: 2069;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.35;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.63. 

Calendar year: 2070;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.35;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.67. 

Calendar year: 2071;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.35;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.72. 

Calendar year: 2072;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.36;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.77. 

Calendar year: 2073;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.36;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.81. 

Calendar year: 2074;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.36;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.85. 

Calendar year: 2075;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.36;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.9. 

Calendar year: 2076;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.37;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.94. 

Calendar year: 2077;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.37;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 18.99. 

Calendar year: 2078;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.37;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 19.03. 

Calendar year: 2079;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.37;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 19.08. 

Calendar year: 2080;
OASI and DI Combined: Income Rate: 13.38;
OASI and DI Combined: Cost Rate: 19.12. 

Source: Social Security Administration, Office of the Chief Actuary, 
intermediate assumptions. 

[End of figure]

2. What are the root causes of this gap between costs and revenues? 

Life expectancy has increased continually since the 1930s, and further 
improvements are expected. As a result of this, along with the aging of 
the baby boom generation, the aged population is growing dramatically. 
(See Fig. 7.) Today, those aged 65 and over are 12 percent of the 
population. In 30 years, they will be more than 20 percent of the 
population. 

Figure 7: The Aged Are Growing as a Share of the Total Population: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Line graph with 131 items. 

Year: 1950;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 8.00%. 

Year: 1951;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 8.11%. 

Year: 1952;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 8.25%. 

Year: 1953;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 8.39%. 

Year: 1954;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 8.52%. 

Year: 1955;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 8.64%. 

Year: 1956;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 8.71%. 

Year: 1957;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 8.79%. 

Year: 1958;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 8.89%. 

Year: 1959;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.00%. 

Year: 1960;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.09%. 

Year: 1961;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.15%. 

Year: 1962;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.21%. 

Year: 1963;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.26%. 

Year: 1964;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.30%. 

Year: 1965;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.36%. 

Year: 1966;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.42%. 

Year: 1967;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.48%. 

Year: 1968;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.56%. 

Year: 1969;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.64%. 

Year: 1970;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.74%. 

Year: 1971;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.85%. 

Year: 1972;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 9.96%. 

Year: 1973;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 10.08%. 

Year: 1974;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 10.22%. 

Year: 1975;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 10.38%. 

Year: 1976;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 10.54%. 

Year: 1977;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 10.70%. 

Year: 1978;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 10.86%. 

Year: 1979;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 11.01%. 

Year: 1980;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 11.15%. 

Year: 1981;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 11.28%. 

Year: 1982;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 11.42%. 

Year: 1983;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 11.55%. 

Year: 1984;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 11.67%. 

Year: 1985;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 11.79%. 

Year: 1986;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 11.93%. 

Year: 1987;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.05%. 

Year: 1988;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.14%. 

Year: 1989;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.22%. 

Year: 1990;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.30%. 

Year: 1991;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.37%. 

Year: 1992;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.44%. 

Year: 1993;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.48%. 

Year: 1994;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.49%. 

Year: 1995;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.49%. 

Year: 1996;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.48%. 

Year: 1997;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.44%. 

Year: 1998;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.38%. 

Year: 1999;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.32%. 

Year: 2000;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.29%. 

Year: 2001;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.27%. 

Year: 2002;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.24%. 

Year: 2003;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.21%. 

Year: 2004;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.20%. 

Year: 2005;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.20%. 

Year: 2006;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.23%. 

Year: 2007;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.31%. 

Year: 2008;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.42%. 

Year: 2009;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.54%. 

Year: 2010;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.68%. 

Year: 2011;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 12.87%. 

Year: 2012;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 13.15%. 

Year: 2013;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 13.45%. 

Year: 2014;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 13.76%. 

Year: 2015;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 14.08%. 

Year: 2016;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 14.40%. 

Year: 2017;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 14.73%. 

Year: 2018;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 15.07%. 

Year: 2019;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 15.45%. 

Year: 2020;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 15.85%. 

Year: 2021;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 16.25%. 

Year: 2022;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 16.65%. 

Year: 2023;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 17.06%. 

Year: 2024;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 17.46%. 

Year: 2025;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 17.87%. 

Year: 2026;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 18.25%. 

Year: 2027;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 18.60%. 

Year: 2028;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 18.93%. 

Year: 2029;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 19.24%. 

Year: 2030;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 19.52%. 

Year: 2031;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 19.73%. 

Year: 2032;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 19.88%. 

Year: 2033;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.02%. 

Year: 2034;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.17%. 

Year: 2035;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.34%. 

Year: 2036;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.48%. 

Year: 2037;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.56%. 

Year: 2038;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.60%. 

Year: 2039;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.62%. 

Year: 2040;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.63%. 

Year: 2041;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.63%. 

Year: 2042;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.64%. 

Year: 2043;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.66%. 

Year: 2044;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.71%. 

Year: 2045;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.79%. 

Year: 2046;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.87%. 

Year: 2047;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.93%. 

Year: 2048;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 20.97%. 

Year: 2049;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.01%. 

Year: 2050;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.06%. 

Year: 2051;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.10%. 

Year: 2052;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.15%. 

Year: 2053;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.21%. 

Year: 2054;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.30%. 

Year: 2055;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.41%. 

Year: 2056;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.52%. 

Year: 2057;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.62%. 

Year: 2058;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.72%. 

Year: 2059;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.80%. 

Year: 2060;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.89%. 

Year: 2061;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 21.96%. 

Year: 2062;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.02%. 

Year: 2063;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.08%. 

Year: 2064;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.15%. 

Year: 2065;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.24%. 

Year: 2066;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.35%. 

Year: 2067;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.47%. 

Year: 2068;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.56%. 

Year: 2069;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.61%. 

Year: 2070;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.66%. 

Year: 2071;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.71%. 

Year: 2072;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.76%. 

Year: 2073;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.81%. 

Year: 2074;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.86%. 

Year: 2075;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.92%. 

Year: 2076;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 22.97%. 

Year: 2077;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 23.02%. 

Year: 2078;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 23.08%. 

Year: 2079;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 23.14%. 

Year: 2080;
Population aged 65 and over (percentage of total population): 23.19%. 

Source: Office of the Chief Actuary, Social Security Administration. 

Note: Projections based on the intermediate assumptions of the 2005 
Trustees' Report. 

[End of figure]

At the same time, the growth of the labor force is expected to slow 
dramatically. Fertility rates are falling. The fertility rate is the 
average number of children born to women during their childbearing 
years. In the 1960s, the rate was an average of 3 children per woman. 
Today it is a little over 2 and is expected to fall somewhat further 
and remain lower than what it takes to maintain a stable population. In 
addition, the relatively rapid growth of participation in the labor 
force by older women is expected to slow. Baby boomers will also be 
leaving the labor force as they retire. By 2025, labor force growth is 
expected to be less than a third of what it is today. (See Fig. 8.) 

Figure 8: Labor Force Growth Is Expected to be Negligible by 2050: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Line graph with 111 items. 

Year: 1970;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.38%. 

Year: 1971;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.56%. 

Year: 1972;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.64%. 

Year: 1973;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.52%. 

Year: 1974;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.64%. 

Year: 1975;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.6%. 

Year: 1976;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.72%. 

Year: 1977;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.68%. 

Year: 1978;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.66%. 

Year: 1979;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.48%. 

Year: 1980;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 2.18%. 

Year: 1981;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.76%. 

Year: 1982;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.58%. 

Year: 1983;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.54%. 

Year: 1984;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.64%. 

Year: 1985;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.7%. 

Year: 1986;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.76%. 

Year: 1987;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.76%. 

Year: 1988;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.74%. 

Year: 1989;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.4%. 

Year: 1990;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.34%. 

Year: 1991;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.2%. 

Year: 1992;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.12%. 

Year: 1993;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1%. 

Year: 1994;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.16%. 

Year: 1995;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.24%. 

Year: 1996;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.28%. 

Year: 1997;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.24%. 

Year: 1998;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.5%. 

Year: 1999;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.42%. 

Year: 2000;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.22%. 

Year: 2001;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.24%. 

Year: 2002;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.12%. 

Year: 2003;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.98%. 

Year: 2004;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.1%. 

Year: 2005;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.24%. 

Year: 2006;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.22%. 

Year: 2007;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1.16%. 

Year: 2008;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 1%. 

Year: 2009;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.88%. 

Year: 2010;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.78%. 

Year: 2011;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.72%. 

Year: 2012;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.68%. 

Year: 2013;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.62%. 

Year: 2014;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.56%. 

Year: 2015;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.54%. 

Year: 2016;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.5%. 

Year: 2017;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.46%. 

Year: 2018;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.42%. 

Year: 2019;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.38%. 

Year: 2020;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.34%. 

Year: 2021;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.32%. 

Year: 2022;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.28%. 

Year: 2023;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.26%. 

Year: 2024;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.24%. 

Year: 2025;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.22%. 

Year: 2026;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.22%. 

Year: 2027;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.22%. 

Year: 2028;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.22%. 

Year: 2029;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.22%. 

Year: 2030;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.24%. 

Year: 2031;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.24%. 

Year: 2032;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.26%. 

Year: 2033;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.28%. 

Year: 2034;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2035;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2036;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2037;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2038;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2039;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2040;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2041;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2042;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2043;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.3%. 

Year: 2044;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.28%. 

Year: 2045;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.26%. 

Year: 2046;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.24%. 

Year: 2047;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.22%. 

Year: 2048;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2049;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2050;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2051;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2052;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2053;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2054;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2055;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2056;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2057;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2058;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2059;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2060;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2061;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2062;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2063;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2064;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2065;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2066;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2067;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2068;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2069;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2070;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2071;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2072;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2073;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2074;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2075;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2076;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2077;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2078;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2079;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Year: 2080;
Percentage change (5-yr moving average): 0.2%. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the Office of the Chief Actuary, 
Social Security Administration. 

Note: This analysis is based on the intermediate assumptions of the 
2005 Social Security trustees' report. The percentage change is 
calculated as a centered 5-year moving average. 

[End of figure]

As a result of the aging population and the slower labor force growth, 
fewer workers will be contributing to Social Security for each aged, 
disabled, dependent, or surviving beneficiary. While 3.3 workers 
support each Social Security beneficiary today, only 2 workers are 
expected to be supporting each beneficiary by 2040. (See Fig. 9.) 

Figure 9: Social Security Workers per Beneficiary: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Line graph with 25 items. 

Year: 1960;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 5.1. 

Year: 1965;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 4. 

Year: 1970;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 3.7. 

Year: 1975;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 3.2. 

Year: 1980;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 3.2. 

Year: 1985;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 3.3. 

Year: 1990;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 3.4. 

Year: 1995;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 3.3. 

Year: 2000;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 3.4. 

Year: 2005;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 3.3. 

Year: 2010;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 3.2. 

Year: 2015;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2.9. 

Year: 2020;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2.6. 

Year: 2025;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2.3. 

Year: 2030;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2.2. 

Year: 2035;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2.1. 

Year: 2040;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2. 

Year: 2045;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2. 

Year: 2050;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2. 

Year: 2055;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2. 

Year: 2060;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 2. 

Year: 2065;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 1.9. 

Year: 2070;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 1.9. 

Year: 2075;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 1.9. 

Year: 2080;
Covered workers per OASDI beneficiary: 1.9. 

Source: Office of the Chief Actuary, Social Security Administration. 

Note: This analysis is based on the intermediate assumptions of the 
2005 Social Security Trustees' Report. 

[End of figure]

3. When does the money run out? 

The Social Security trust funds are projected to be able to pay full 
benefits until 2041.[Footnote 2] Today baby boomers are still all of 
working age, and annual Social Security trust fund income exceeds 
benefit payments. This annual cash surplus is expected to continue 
until 2017 and help build up the trust fund balances. After that time, 
annual benefit payments are expected to exceed income, but interest 
income will more than make up the difference. (See Fig. 10.) Beginning 
in 2027, Trust fund balances are expected to then decline rapidly until 
they are exhausted in 2041. At that time, annual income will only be 
sufficient to pay about 74 percent of promised benefits. By 2079, 
income will only be sufficient to pay about 68 percent of promised 
benefits. 

Figure 10: Social Security's Trust Fund Balance Grows but then Declines 
Rapidly after 2027: 

[See PDF for image] --graphic text: 

Line graph with 36 items. 

Year: 2005;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $1.85. 

Year: 2006;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $1.99. 

Year: 2007;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.14. 

Year: 2008;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.29. 

Year: 2009;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.43. 

Year: 2010;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.57. 

Year: 2011;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.72. 

Year: 2012;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.86. 

Year: 2013;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.99. 

Year: 2014;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.11. 

Year: 2015;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.22. 

Year: 2016;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.32. 

Year: 2017;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.41. 

Year: 2018;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.48. 

Year: 2019;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.54. 

Year: 2020;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.58. 

Year: 2021;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.61. 

Year: 2022;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.61. 

Year: 2023;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.59. 

Year: 2024;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.55. 

Year: 2025;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.49. 

Year: 2026;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.41. 

Year: 2027;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.30. 

Year: 2028;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.17. 

Year: 2029;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $3.02. 

Year: 2030;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.85. 

Year: 2031;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.65. 

Year: 2032;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.44. 

Year: 2033;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $2.21. 

Year: 2034;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $1.96. 

Year: 2035;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $1.69. 

Year: 2036;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $1.40. 

Year: 2037;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $1.10. 

Year: 2038;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $0.78. 

Year: 2039;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $0.45. 

Year: 2040;
Trillions of 2005 dollars: $0.10. 

Source: Social Security Administration, Office of the Chief Actuary, 
intermediate assumptions. 

[End of figure]

4. How big is the funding gap in dollars? 

Actuaries have a variety of ways of answering this question. One 
approach gives an answer of $4 trillion, another approach gives an 
answer of $11.1 trillion, and yet a third approach gives an answer of 
$12 trillion, each in net present value. What's the difference? The 
estimate of $4 trillion represents the additional amount needed today, 
which along with the program's annual tax revenues and earnings on the 
trust fund balances would suffice to pay all the projected annual costs 
over the next 75 years.[Footnote 3] This is how much it would cost in 
2005 dollars to restore 75-year solvency. This approach to measuring 
the funding gap reflects the adequacy of financing for a pay-as-you-go 
system. The estimate of $11.1 trillion represents the same difference 
between costs and income, except over an infinite time 
horizon.[Footnote 4] The estimate of $12 trillion reflects a change 
from the current pay-as-you-go system to a system that is fully advance 
funded. This Figure is the additional amount needed today, which along 
with lifetime payroll tax contributions and earnings on the trust fund 
balances would suffice to pay benefits for all those who are already 
participants in 2005.[Footnote 5] By "participants" we include all 
those who are 15 or older and, thus, have already contributed to the 
system as of 2005 but exclude any future workers and beneficiaries who 
have not yet contributed. For a fully advance funded program, this 
value would equal zero. 

In other words, $12 trillion is the value of benefits that past and 
current participants will receive that exceeds what they will have paid 
for. It largely reflects the large transfers already made to earlier 
generations in the start up phase of a pay-as-you-go system. By its 
nature, a pay-as-you-go system will always have a large unfunded 
obligation. However, in a pay-as-you-go system, to the extent that 
future generations are willing and able to pay more in taxes, this 
unfunded liability can be rolled over from generation to generation 
indefinitely. 

5. Which horizon should we be looking at: 75 years or an infinite 
horizon? 

Both. Each horizon is helpful, providing useful but different 
information. However, a horizon is not as important to focus on as the 
concept of sustainability, and on this point each horizon leads to the 
same conclusion. As Figure 6 shows, the gap between costs and income 
continues to widen through the end of the 75-year period. As each year 
passes, another deficit year gets factored into the solvency estimate 
and makes it worse. So even if we restored solvency over the next 75 
years, we would only face another 75-year deficit next year. 
Sustainable solvency would require finding a solution that would 
eliminate the gap between costs and income on a continuing basis beyond 
the 75-year period. Using an infinite horizon is one way to look at 
sustainability beyond the 75-year period. Another way to look at 
sustainability would be to examine the trend in costs versus income 
beyond the 75 years. Still another way would be to examine the share of 
the budget and the economy that Social Security consumes. 

Historically, the question of the appropriate time horizon has shifted 
back and forth. The 1965 Advisory Council on Social Security criticized 
previous efforts to use an infinite horizon, saying that it "serves no 
useful purpose;" it suggested using the current 75-year horizon. In 
contrast, the 2003 Technical Panel on Assumptions and Methods endorsed 
using the infinite horizon in addition to the 75-year horizon. Still, 
the panel advised that the methodologies for the infinite horizon 
needed to be carefully examined. [Footnote 6] The technical panel 
further indicated that, referring to estimates from the 2003 trustees' 
report, the $10.5 trillion estimate is a "large figure" but that it 
needed to be seen in the context of the present value of taxable 
payroll over the infinite horizon, which is on the order of $275 
trillion. The panel also believed that infinite horizon projections 
should emphasize the measure as a percentage of taxable 
payroll.[Footnote 7]

According to the 2005 trustees' report, over the 75-year horizon the 
unfunded obligation equals 1.8 percent of taxable payroll, while over 
an infinite horizon it equals 3.5 percent of taxable payroll. In other 
words, an immediate increase in the payroll tax of 1.8 percent would 
restore solvency over the next 75 years, while an immediate increase of 
3.5 percent would restore solvency over an infinite horizon, given 
current assumptions. 

No matter which horizon you use or how you look at sustainability, it 
is important to keep in mind that estimating future outcomes is 
inherently difficult, and using different assumptions can dramatically 
alter the estimates. Therefore, in evaluating Social Security reform 
proposals, it is helpful to focus on the differences between the 
proposals rather than on the precise values of the estimates for any 
one scenario. Focusing on the differences helps neutralize the 
limitations of the assumptions used. 

6. Are there any issues other than solvency that call for reform? 

In recent years, reform proposals have contained a variety of 
provisions to address concerns other than restoring long-term solvency. 
Such concerns include: 

* mitigating persistent poverty among very elderly widows and those 
with low lifetime earnings;

* making Social Security coverage universal, that is, covering jobs 
that are not currently covered, such as some state and local government 
jobs; and: 

* redressing the effects of increasing earnings inequality on the 
program's distributional outcomes. 

OVERALL FISCAL AND ECONOMIC OUTLOOK: 

7. When Social Security's benefit payments exceed its income, where 
will the money come from? 

Absent other changes, benefit costs will exceed income in 2017. The 
trust funds will have large reserves, plus interest income on these 
reserves, to help pay benefits, but benefits must be paid in cash, not 
in government securities. Starting in 2017, the Treasury Department 
will begin to redeem trust fund securities in order to continue to pay 
full promised benefits. Specifically, in order to convert the Trust 
Fund securities into cash, the government will require increased 
government revenue, increased borrowing from the public, or reduced 
spending in the rest of the government.[Footnote 8] So, even though the 
trust funds will be able to pay full Social Security benefits until 
2041, redeeming their Treasury securities will have an adverse impact 
on the federal budget much sooner. In fact, in 2009, Social Security's 
cash surplus starts to decline. To finance the same level of federal 
spending as in the previous year, the federal budget will need 
additional revenues and/or increased borrowing, since Social Security's 
surplus partially offsets the deficit in the rest of the government's 
accounts. Assuming no additional revenues or spending cuts, budget 
deficits for the federal government as a whole will increase. 

Ultimately, the critical question is not how much the OASDI trust fund 
has in assets. Rather, it is whether the government as a whole can 
afford to pay the benefits in the future, and how those benefits 
compete with other claims on scarce resources? Furthermore, what is the 
capacity of the economy and budget to afford the commitment? 

8. What is the outlook for the whole federal budget and its capacity to 
pay benefits, especially when Medicare and Medicaid are included? 

The challenge posed by the growth in Social Security spending becomes 
even more significant in combination with the more rapid expected 
growth in Medicare and Medicaid spending. Medicare presents a much 
greater, more complex, and more urgent fiscal challenge than does 
Social Security. Medicare growth rates reflect not only a burgeoning 
beneficiary population but also the escalation of health care costs at 
rates well exceeding general rates of inflation. For example, increases 
in the number and quality of health care services have been fueled by 
the explosive growth of medical technology.[Footnote 9] This growth in 
spending on federal entitlements for retirees will become increasingly 
unsustainable over the long term. The increasing fiscal pressure will 
reduce budgetary flexibility further. Over the past few decades, 
spending on mandatory programs--entitlement programs such as Social 
Security and Medicare--has consumed an increasing share of the federal 
budget. In 1964, prior to the creation of the Medicare and Medicaid 
programs, spending for mandatory programs plus net interest accounted 
for about 33 percent of total federal spending.[Footnote 10] By 2004, 
this share had almost doubled to approximately 61 percent of the 
budget. (See Fig. 11.) 

Figure 11: Federal Spending for Mandatory and Discretionary Programs, 
Fiscal Years 1964, 1984, and 2004: 

[See PDF for image] - graphic text: 

3 pie charts with 3 items each. 

1964: 

Discretionary: 67%;
Mandatory: 26%;
Net Interest: 7%. 

1984: 

Discretionary: 45%;
Mandatory: 42%;
Net Interest: 13%. 

2004: 

Discretionary: 39%;
Mandatory: 54%;
Net Interest: 7%. 

Source: Office of Management and Budget. 

Note: Discretionary programs are those programs controlled by Congress 
through the annual appropriations process. They include a wide range of 
programs such as defense, environmental, education and other programs. 

[End of figure]

Moreover, our nation faces growing budget deficits and interest costs. 
Assuming, for example, that all expiring tax provisions are extended 
and discretionary spending keeps pace with the economy, by 2040 total 
federal revenues may be adequate to pay no more than interest on the 
federal debt. (See Fig. 12.) To obtain balance, massive spending cuts, 
tax increases, or some combination of the two would be necessary. 
Slowing the growth of discretionary spending and allowing the tax 
reductions to sunset will not eliminate the imbalance.[Footnote 11]

Figure 12: Composition of Spending as a Share of GDP, Assuming 
Discretionary Spending Grows with GDP After 2004 and All Expiring Tax 
Provisions Are Extended: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Line/Stacked Bar combo chart with 4 groups, 1 line (Revenue) and 4 bars 
per group. 

2004;
Net interest: 1.4%;
Social Security: 4.3%;
Medicare & Medicaid: 3.8%;
All other spending: 10.4%;
Revenue: 16.3%. 

2015;
Net interest: 2.8%;
Social Security: 4.7%;
Medicare & Medicaid: 5.2%;
All other spending: 9.7%;
Revenue: 17.4. 

2030;
Net interest: 7.7%;
Social Security: 6.7%;
Medicare & Medicaid: 8%;
All other spending: 9.7%;
Revenue: 17.4%. 

2040;
Net interest: 15.7%;
Social Security: 7.9%;
Medicare & Medicaid: 9.7%;
All other spending: 9.7%;
Revenue: 17.4%. 

Source: GAO's March 2005 analysis. 

Note: Although expiring tax provisions are extended, revenue as a share 
of GDP increases through 2015 due to (1) real bracket creep, (2) more 
taxpayers becoming subject to the AMT, and (3) increased revenue from 
tax-deferred retirement accounts. After 2015, revenue as a share of GDP 
is held constant. 

[End of figure]

9. What are the implications of this budgetary outlook for the economy 
as a whole? 

Figure 13 shows the total future draw on the economy represented by 
Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid. Under the 2005 Trustees' 
intermediate estimates and CBO's long-term Medicaid estimates, spending 
for these entitlement programs combined will grow to 15.2 percent of 
GDP in 2030 from today's 8.5 percent. Taken together, Social Security, 
Medicare, and Medicaid represent an unsustainable burden on future 
generations. 

Figure 13: Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid Spending as a 
Percentage of GDP: 

[See PDF for image] - graphic text: 

Area graph with 81 Groups and 3 items per Group. 

2000: Total value: 7.75% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 2.29% of GDP, which is 29.5% of 2000 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.23% of GDP, which is 15.9% of 2000 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.23% of GDP, which is 54.6% of 2000 spending. 

2001: Total value: 8.14% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 2.46% of GDP, which is 30.2% of 2001 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.33% of GDP, which is 16.3% of 2001 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.35% of GDP, which is 53.4% of 2001 spending. 

2002: Total value: 8.4% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 2.55% of GDP, which is 30.4% of 2002 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.44% of GDP, which is 17.1% of 2002 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.41% of GDP, which is 52.5% of 2002 spending. 

2003: Total value: 8.44% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 2.59% of GDP, which is 30.7% of 2003 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.49% of GDP, which is 17.7% of 2003 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.36% of GDP, which is 51.7% of 2003 spending. 

2004: Total value: 8.52% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 2.68% of GDP, which is 31.5% of 2004 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.51% of GDP, which is 17.7% of 2004 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.33% of GDP, which is 50.8% of 2004 spending. 

2005: Total value: 8.52% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 2.76% of GDP, which is 32.4% of 2005 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.48% of GDP, which is 17.4% of 2005 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.28% of GDP, which is 50.2% of 2005 spending. 

2006: Total value: 9.16% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 3.44% of GDP, which is 37.6% of 2006 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.47% of GDP, which is 16.0% of 2006 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.25% of GDP, which is 46.4% of 2006 spending. 

2007: Total value: 9.23% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 3.51% of GDP, which is 38.0% of 2007 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.49% of GDP, which is 16.1% of 2007 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.23% of GDP, which is 45.8% of 2007 spending. 

2008: Total value: 9.34% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 3.56% of GDP, which is 38.1% of 2008 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.54% of GDP, which is 16.5% of 2008 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.24% of GDP, which is 45.4% of 2008 spending. 

2009: Total value: 9.49% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 3.61% of GDP, which is 38.0% of 2009 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.6% of GDP, which is 16.9% of 2009 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.28% of GDP, which is 45.1% of 2009 spending. 

2010: Total value: 9.64% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 3.66% of GDP, which is 38.0% of 2010 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.66% of GDP, which is 17.2% of 2010 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.32% of GDP, which is 44.8% of 2010 spending. 

2011: Total value: 9.82% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 3.72% of GDP, which is 37.9% of 2011 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.73% of GDP, which is 17.6% of 2011 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.37% of GDP, which is 44.5% of 2011 spending. 

2012: Total value: 10.06% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 3.81% of GDP, which is 37.9% of 2012 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.8% of GDP, which is 17.9% of 2012 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.45% of GDP, which is 44.2% of 2012 spending. 

2013: Total value: 10.34% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 3.93% of GDP, which is 38.0% of 2013 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.87% of GDP, which is 18.1% of 2013 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.54% of GDP, which is 43.9% of 2013 spending. 

2014: Total value: 10.6% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 4.07% of GDP, which is 38.4% of 2014 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.9% of GDP, which is 17.9% of 2014 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.63% of GDP, which is 43.7% of 2014 spending. 

2015: Total value: 10.88% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 4.24% of GDP, which is 39.0% of 2015 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.9% of GDP, which is 17.5% of 2015 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.74% of GDP, which is 43.6% of 2015 spending. 

2016: Total value: 11.15% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 4.4% of GDP, which is 39.5% of 2016 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.9% of GDP, which is 17.0% of 2016 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.85% of GDP, which is 43.5% of 2016 spending. 

2017: Total value: 11.41% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 4.55% of GDP, which is 39.9% of 2017 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.9% of GDP, which is 16.7% of 2017 spending. 
Social Security value: 4.96% of GDP, which is 43.5% of 2017 spending. 

2018: Total value: 11.69% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 4.72% of GDP, which is 40.4% of 2018 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.9% of GDP, which is 16.3% of 2018 spending. 
Social Security value: 5.07% of GDP, which is 43.4% of 2018 spending. 

2019: Total value: 12% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 4.89% of GDP, which is 40.8% of 2019 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.92% of GDP, which is 16.0% of 2019 spending. 
Social Security value: 5.19% of GDP, which is 43.3% of 2019 spending. 

2020: Total value: 12.35% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 5.08% of GDP, which is 41.1% of 2020 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.95% of GDP, which is 15.8% of 2020 spending. 
Social Security value: 5.32% of GDP, which is 43.1% of 2020 spending. 

2021: Total value: 12.69% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 5.26% of GDP, which is 41.4% of 2021 spending. 
Medicaid value: 1.99% of GDP, which is 15.7% of 2021 spending. 
Social Security value: 5.44% of GDP, which is 42.9% of 2021 spending. 

2022: Total value: 13.02% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 5.45% of GDP, which is 41.9% of 2022 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.02% of GDP, which is 15.5% of 2022 spending. 
Social Security value: 5.55% of GDP, which is 42.6% of 2022 spending. 

2023: Total value: 13.37% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 5.64% of GDP, which is 42.2% of 2023 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.06% of GDP, which is 15.4% of 2023 spending. 
Social Security value: 5.67% of GDP, which is 42.4% of 2023 spending. 

2024: Total value: 13.71% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 5.84% of GDP, which is 42.6% of 2024 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.09% of GDP, which is 15.2% of 2024 spending. 
Social Security value: 5.78% of GDP, which is 42.2% of 2024 spending. 

2025: Total value: 14.06% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 6.04% of GDP, which is 43.0% of 2025 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.13% of GDP, which is 15.1% of 2025 spending. 
Social Security value: 5.89% of GDP, which is 41.9% of 2025 spending. 

2026: Total value: 14.38% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 6.22% of GDP, which is 43.3% of 2026 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.17% of GDP, which is 15.1% of 2026 spending. 
Social Security value: 5.99% of GDP, which is 41.7% of 2026 spending. 

2027: Total value: 14.68% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 6.4% of GDP, which is 43.6% of 2027 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.2% of GDP, which is 15.0% of 2027 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.08% of GDP, which is 41.4% of 2027 spending. 

2028: Total value: 14.98% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 6.58% of GDP, which is 43.9% of 2028 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.23% of GDP, which is 14.9% of 2028 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.17% of GDP, which is 41.2% of 2028 spending. 

2029: Total value: 15.28% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 6.77% of GDP, which is 44.3% of 2029 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.27% of GDP, which is 14.9% of 2029 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.24% of GDP, which is 40.8% of 2029 spending. 

2030: Total value: 15.57% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 6.95% of GDP, which is 44.6% of 2030 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.31% of GDP, which is 14.8% of 2030 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.31% of GDP, which is 40.5% of 2030 spending. 

2031: Total value: 15.83% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 7.11% of GDP, which is 44.9% of 2031 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.35% of GDP, which is 14.8% of 2031 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.37% of GDP, which is 40.2% of 2031 spending. 

2032: Total value: 16.08% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 7.26% of GDP, which is 45.1% of 2032 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.4% of GDP, which is 14.9% of 2032 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.42% of GDP, which is 39.9% of 2032 spending. 

2033: Total value: 16.33% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 7.42% of GDP, which is 45.4% of 2033 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.45% of GDP, which is 15.0% of 2033 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.46% of GDP, which is 39.6% of 2033 spending. 

2034: Total value: 16.58% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 7.58% of GDP, which is 45.7% of 2034 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.5% of GDP, which is 15.1% of 2034 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.5% of GDP, which is 39.2% of 2034 spending. 

2035: Total value: 16.82% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 7.75% of GDP, which is 46.1% of 2035 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.55% of GDP, which is 15.2% of 2035 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.52% of GDP, which is 38.8% of 2035 spending. 

2036: Total value: 17.04% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 7.9% of GDP, which is 46.4% of 2036 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.6% of GDP, which is 15.3% of 2036 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.54% of GDP, which is 38.4% of 2036 spending. 

2037: Total value: 17.24% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 8.04% of GDP, which is 46.6% of 2037 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.65% of GDP, which is 15.4% of 2037 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.55% of GDP, which is 38.0% of 2037 spending. 

2038: Total value: 17.42% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 8.17% of GDP, which is 46.9% of 2038 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.7% of GDP, which is 15.5% of 2038 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.55% of GDP, which is 37.6% of 2038 spending. 

2039: Total value: 17.59% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 8.29% of GDP, which is 47.1% of 2039 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.75% of GDP, which is 15.6% of 2039 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.55% of GDP, which is 37.2% of 2039 spending. 

2040: Total value: 17.75% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 8.41% of GDP, which is 47.4% of 2040 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.8% of GDP, which is 15.8% of 2040 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.54% of GDP, which is 36.8% of 2040 spending. 

2041: Total value: 17.91% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 8.53% of GDP, which is 47.6% of 2041 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.85% of GDP, which is 15.9% of 2041 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.53% of GDP, which is 36.5% of 2041 spending. 

2042: Total value: 18.07% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 8.64% of GDP, which is 47.8% of 2042 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.9% of GDP, which is 16.0% of 2042 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.53% of GDP, which is 36.1% of 2042 spending. 

2043: Total value: 18.23% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 8.76% of GDP, which is 48.1% of 2043 spending. 
Medicaid value: 2.95% of GDP, which is 16.2% of 2043 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.52% of GDP, which is 35.8% of 2043 spending. 

2044: Total value: 18.39% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 8.88% of GDP, which is 48.3% of 2044 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3% of GDP, which is 16.3% of 2044 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.51% of GDP, which is 35.4% of 2044 spending. 

2045: Total value: 18.55% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 9% of GDP, which is 48.5% of 2045 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.05% of GDP, which is 16.4% of 2045 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.5% of GDP, which is 35.0% of 2045 spending. 

2046: Total value: 18.71% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 9.12% of GDP, which is 48.7% of 2046 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.1% of GDP, which is 16.6% of 2046 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.49% of GDP, which is 34.7% of 2046 spending. 

2047: Total value: 18.86% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 9.23% of GDP, which is 48.9% of 2047 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.14% of GDP, which is 16.6% of 2047 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.49% of GDP, which is 34.4% of 2047 spending. 

2048: Total value: 19% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 9.33% of GDP, which is 49.1% of 2048 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.19% of GDP, which is 16.8% of 2048 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.48% of GDP, which is 34.1% of 2048 spending. 

2049: Total value: 19.15% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 9.44% of GDP, which is 49.3% of 2049 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.23% of GDP, which is 16.9% of 2049 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.48% of GDP, which is 33.8% of 2049 spending. 

2050: Total value: 19.3% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 9.56% of GDP, which is 49.5% of 2050 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.27% of GDP, which is 16.9% of 2050 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.47% of GDP, which is 33.5% of 2050 spending. 

2051: Total value: 19.45% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 9.67% of GDP, which is 49.7% of 2051 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.31% of GDP, which is 17.0% of 2051 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.47% of GDP, which is 33.3% of 2051 spending. 

2052: Total value: 19.61% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 9.78% of GDP, which is 49.9% of 2052 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.35% of GDP, which is 17.1% of 2052 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.48% of GDP, which is 33.0% of 2052 spending. 

2053: Total value: 19.77% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 9.9% of GDP, which is 50.1% of 2053 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.39% of GDP, which is 17.1% of 2053 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.48% of GDP, which is 32.8% of 2053 spending. 

2054: Total value: 19.96% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 10.03% of GDP, which is 50.3% of 2054 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.44% of GDP, which is 17.2% of 2054 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.49% of GDP, which is 32.5% of 2054 spending. 

2055: Total value: 20.13% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 10.16% of GDP, which is 50.5% of 2055 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.48% of GDP, which is 17.3% of 2055 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.49% of GDP, which is 32.2% of 2055 spending. 

2056: Total value: 20.32% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 10.3% of GDP, which is 50.7% of 2056 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.52% of GDP, which is 17.3% of 2056 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.5% of GDP, which is 32.0% of 2056 spending. 

2057: Total value: 20.52% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 10.44% of GDP, which is 50.9% of 2057 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.57% of GDP, which is 17.4% of 2057 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.51% of GDP, which is 31.7% of 2057 spending. 

2058: Total value: 20.72% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 10.59% of GDP, which is 51.1% of 2058 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.61% of GDP, which is 17.4% of 2058 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.52% of GDP, which is 31.5% of 2058 spending. 

2059: Total value: 20.92% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 10.74% of GDP, which is 51.3% of 2059 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.66% of GDP, which is 17.5% of 2059 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.52% of GDP, which is 31.2% of 2059 spending. 

2060: Total value: 21.12% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 10.89% of GDP, which is 51.6% of 2060 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.7% of GDP, which is 17.5% of 2060 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.53% of GDP, which is 30.9% of 2060 spending. 

2061: Total value: 21.33% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 11.04% of GDP, which is 51.8% of 2061 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.75% of GDP, which is 17.6% of 2061 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.54% of GDP, which is 30.7% of 2061 spending. 

2062: Total value: 21.54% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 11.19% of GDP, which is 51.9% of 2062 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.8% of GDP, which is 17.6% of 2062 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.55% of GDP, which is 30.4% of 2062 spending. 

2063: Total value: 21.74% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 11.34% of GDP, which is 52.2% of 2063 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.84% of GDP, which is 17.7% of 2063 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.56% of GDP, which is 30.2% of 2063 spending. 

2064: Total value: 21.96% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 11.51% of GDP, which is 52.4% of 2064 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.89% of GDP, which is 17.7% of 2064 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.56% of GDP, which is 29.9% of 2064 spending. 

2065: Total value: 22.19% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 11.68% of GDP, which is 52.6% of 2065 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.94% of GDP, which is 17.8% of 2065 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.57% of GDP, which is 29.6% of 2065 spending. 

2066: Total value: 22.43% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 11.86% of GDP, which is 52.9% of 2066 spending. 
Medicaid value: 3.99% of GDP, which is 17.8% of 2066 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.58% of GDP, which is 29.3% of 2066 spending. 

2067: Total value: 22.66% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 12.03% of GDP, which is 53.1% of 2067 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.04% of GDP, which is 17.8% of 2067 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.59% of GDP, which is 29.1% of 2067 spending. 

2068: Total value: 22.87% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 12.19% of GDP, which is 53.3% of 2068 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.09% of GDP, which is 17.9% of 2068 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.59% of GDP, which is 28.8% of 2068 spending. 

2069: Total value: 23.08% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 12.35% of GDP, which is 53.5% of 2069 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.14% of GDP, which is 17.9% of 2069 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.59% of GDP, which is 28.6% of 2069 spending. 

2070: Total value: 23.3% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 12.51% of GDP, which is 53.7% of 2070 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.19% of GDP, which is 18.0% of 2070 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.6% of GDP, which is 28.3% of 2070 spending. 

2071: Total value: 23.53% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 12.68% of GDP, which is 53.9% of 2071 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.25% of GDP, which is 18.1% of 2071 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.6% of GDP, which is 28.0% of 2071 spending. 

2072: Total value: 23.74% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 12.84% of GDP, which is 54.1% of 2072 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.3% of GDP, which is 18.1% of 2072 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.6% of GDP, which is 27.8% of 2072 spending. 

2073: Total value: 23.97% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 13.01% of GDP, which is 54.3% of 2073 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.35% of GDP, which is 18.1% of 2073 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.61% of GDP, which is 27.6% of 2073 spending. 

2074: Total value: 24.19% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 13.17% of GDP, which is 54.4% of 2074 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.41% of GDP, which is 18.2% of 2074 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.61% of GDP, which is 27.3% of 2074 spending. 

2075: Total value: 24.41% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 13.34% of GDP, which is 54.6% of 2075 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.46% of GDP, which is 18.3% of 2075 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.61% of GDP, which is 27.1% of 2075 spending. 

2076: Total value: 24.639% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 13.509% of GDP, which is 54.8% of 2076 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.52% of GDP, which is 18.3% of 2076 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.61% of GDP, which is 26.8% of 2076 spending. 

2077: Total value: 24.869% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 13.679% of GDP, which is 55.0% of 2077 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.57% of GDP, which is 18.4% of 2077 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.62% of GDP, which is 26.6% of 2077 spending. 

2078: Total value: 25.1% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 13.85% of GDP, which is 55.2% of 2078 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.63% of GDP, which is 18.4% of 2078 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.62% of GDP, which is 26.4% of 2078 spending. 

2079: Total value: 25.16% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 13.85% of GDP, which is 55.0% of 2079 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.69% of GDP, which is 18.6% of 2079 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.62% of GDP, which is 26.3% of 2079 spending. 

2080: Total value: 25.23% of GDP. 
Medicare value: 13.85% of GDP, which is 54.9% of 2080 spending. 
Medicaid value: 4.75% of GDP, which is 18.8% of 2080 spending. 
Social Security value: 6.63% of GDP, which is 26.3% of 2080 spending. 

Source: GAO analysis based on data from the Office of the Chief 
Actuary, Social Security Administration, Office of the Actuary, Centers 
for Medicare and Medicaid Services, and the Congressional Budget 
Office. 

Note: Social Security and Medicare projections based on the 
intermediate assumptions of the 2004 Trustees' Reports. Medicaid 
projections based on CBO's January 2004 short-term Medicaid estimates 
and CBO's December 2003 long-term Medicaid projections under mid-range 
assumptions. 

[End of figure]

Although higher economic growth could help ease budgetary pressures, 
the fiscal gap is simply too large for us to grow our way out of the 
problem. Demographic trends and low national saving rates suggest that 
higher economic growth, which is fueled by increases in labor, 
investment, and productivity, will be difficult to achieve. As shown in 
Figure 8 earlier, growth of the labor force is expected to slow 
dramatically and by 2025 is expected to be less than a third of what it 
is today. 

Increased investment could spur economic growth. However, increasing 
investment depends, at least in part, on national saving. One component 
of national saving, personal saving, remains at historically low levels 
(See Figure 14). Traditionally, the most direct way for the federal 
government to increase saving has been to reduce the deficit (or run a 
surplus). Although the government may try to increase personal saving, 
results of these efforts have been mixed. For example, even with the 
preferential tax treatment granted since the 1970s to encourage 
retirement saving, the personal saving rate has steadily declined. 

Figure 14: Annual Personal Saving Rates, 1960-2004: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Line graph with 45 items. 

Year: 1960;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 7.3%. 

Year: 1961;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.4%. 

Year: 1962;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.3%. 

Year: 1963;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 7.8%. 

Year: 1964;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.8%. 

Year: 1965;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.6%. 

Year: 1966;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.3%. 

Year: 1967;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 9.5%. 

Year: 1968;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.4%. 

Year: 1969;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 7.8%. 

Year: 1970;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 9.4%. 

Year: 1971;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 10.1%. 

Year: 1972;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.9%. 

Year: 1973;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 10.5%. 

Year: 1974;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 10.6%. 

Year: 1975;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 10.6%. 

Year: 1976;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 9.4%. 

Year: 1977;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.7%. 

Year: 1978;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.9%. 

Year: 1979;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.9%. 

Year: 1980;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 10%. 

Year: 1981;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 10.9%. 

Year: 1982;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 11.2%. 

Year: 1983;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 9%. 

Year: 1984;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 10.8%. 

Year: 1985;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 9%. 

Year: 1986;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 8.2%. 

Year: 1987;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 7%. 

Year: 1988;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 7.3%. 

Year: 1989;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 7.1%. 

Year: 1990;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 7%. 

Year: 1991;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 7.3%. 

Year: 1992;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 7.7%. 

Year: 1993;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 5.8%. 

Year: 1994;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 4.8%. 

Year: 1995;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 4.6%. 

Year: 1996;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 4%. 

Year: 1997;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 3.6%. 

Year: 1998;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 4.3%. 

Year: 1999;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 2.4%. 

Year: 2000;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 2.3%. 

Year: 2001;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 1.8%. 

Year: 2002;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 2%. 

Year: 2003;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 1.4%. 

Year: 2004;
Percentage of disposable personal income (Personal saving rate): 1.2%. 

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Department of Commerce. 

[End of figure]

CONSEQUENCES OF INACTION: 

10. Why can't we wait for a more immediate solvency crisis to reform 
Social Security? 

Waiting until Social Security faces an immediate solvency crisis could 
reduce the options to only those choices that are the most difficult. 
Acting soon would allow changes to be smaller and to be phased in so 
the individuals who are most likely to be affected, namely younger and 
future workers, will have more time to adjust their retirement 
planning. In addition, acting soon reduces the likelihood that Congress 
will have to choose between imposing severe benefit cuts and unfairly 
burdening future generations with the program's rising costs. Taking 
action soon would also promote increased budgetary flexibility in the 
future, which could lead to greater investment, productivity, and 
stronger economic growth. A successful reform effort would improve 
government credibility and enhance confidence in key financial markets. 
Even if reforms succeed in increasing national saving, it would take 
many years for any resulting economic growth to fully develop. 

Acting soon would also help to ensure that the "miracle of compounding" 
works for us rather than against us. Increasing trust fund balances 
sooner means they have more time to build up with compound interest. 
Conversely, reducing the publicly held debt reduces the compound 
interest payments that taxpayers make on that debt. Some of the 
benefits of early action--and the costs of delay--can be seen in Figure 
15. This Figure compares what it would take to achieve solvency at 
different points in time by either raising payroll taxes or reducing 
benefits.[Footnote 12] If we did nothing until 2041--the year the Trust 
Funds are estimated to be exhausted--achieving actuarial balance would 
require an average reduction in benefits of 29 percent or an increase 
in taxes of 41 percent, or an equivalent combination of benefit 
reductions and tax increases for the period 2041-2079. As Figure 15 
shows, earlier action shrinks the size of the adjustment that would be 
needed now and in the future. 

Figure 15: Size of Action Needed to Achieve Social Security Solvency: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Bar graph with 3 groups of 2 bars each. 

Years: 2005-2079;
Benefit adjustment: 13%;
Tax adjustment: 15%. 

Years: 2017-2079;
Benefit adjustment: 16%;
Tax adjustment: 20%. 

Years: 2041-2079;
Benefit adjustment: 29%; 
Tax adjustment: 41%. 

Source: Office of the Chief Actuary, Social Security Administration. 

Note: This is based on the intermediate assumptions of the 2005 Social 
Security Trustees' Report. The benefit adjustments in this graph 
represent a one-time, permanent change to all existing and future 
benefits beginning in the first year indicated. 

[End of figure]

11. But what happens if we don't do anything? 

If we don't do anything, the system will likely become insolvent and 
pay lower benefits; it will not, though, go bankrupt.[Footnote 13] 
However, because the law does not provide for any procedure for paying 
less than full benefits, it is difficult to say exactly what would 
unfold. One possible scenario of trust fund exhaustion underscores the 
need to take action sooner rather than later. [Footnote 14] Under this 
scenario, full benefits promised under current law would be paid until 
trust fund exhaustion. After that date, benefit payments would be 
adjusted each year to equal annual tax income. Initially, benefits for 
all Social Security recipients would be reduced across the board to 74 
percent of currently scheduled levels. Additional reductions would need 
to be taken in successive years; by the end of the 75-year projection 
period, benefits would be only 68 percent of currently scheduled 
levels. 

This trust fund exhaustion scenario raises significant 
intergenerational equity issues. Specifically, a much greater burden 
would be placed on younger generations than under policy scenarios that 
are phased in over longer periods. Also benefits would be adjusted 
proportionately for all recipients, increasing the likelihood of 
hardship for lower-income retirees and the disabled. 

A FRAMEWORK FOR EVALUATION: 

12. How should we evaluate the various options for Social Security 
reform? 

The Social Security program is so deeply woven into the fabric of our 
nation that any proposed reform must consider the program in its 
entirety, rather than one aspect alone. There are many options and 
trade-offs that need to be considered. Thus, GAO has developed a broad 
framework for evaluating reform proposals that considers not only 
solvency but other aspects of the program as well. Specifically, the 
framework uses three basic criteria: 

* the extent to which a proposal achieves sustainable solvency and how 
it would affect the economy and the federal budget;

* the relative balance struck between the goals of individual equity 
and income adequacy; and: 

* how readily a proposal could be implemented, administered, and 
explained to the public. 

The weight that different policy makers may place on different criteria 
will vary, depending on how they value different attributes. For 
example, if policy makers determine that offering individual choice and 
control is a primary concern, then a reform proposal emphasizing 
individual equity considerations might be preferred. Alternatively, if 
policymakers determine that benefit certainty and security are of 
primary concern, then reform proposals that stress adequacy and 
sustainable solvency might be preferred. As they fashion a 
comprehensive proposal, however, policy makers will 35 ultimately have 
to balance the relative importance they place on each of these 
criteria. 

13. Why do we hear claims about the effects of proposals that directly 
contradict each other? 

In examining the effect of possible reforms to Social Security, many 
analysts use so-called benchmarks as standards of comparison. For 
example, discussions of a reform proposal might discuss the size of 
benefit changes resulting from the reforms. However, calculations of 
benefit changes use some benchmark that assumes something about what 
the benefit levels would be in the absence of reform, implicitly or 
explicitly. Analysts use benchmarks to reflect certain aspects of the 
existing system that they deem important. Because of Social Security's 
long-term insolvency, what benefit levels will be in the absence of 
reform is not at all clear. Revenue increases or benefit reductions, or 
some combination of the two, will be necessary to restore solvency. 
Proponents or opponents of a particular reform might well like to 
calculate benefit changes using a benchmark that is most favorable to 
their position. So it is possible to have proponents and opponents 
discussing exactly the same reform proposal but claiming two totally 
different estimates of what the benefit changes would be. Basing their 
analyses on different benchmarks would lead to such contradictory 
results. This can be a source of great confusion. 

14. What benchmarks should be used for comparison? 

Acknowledging the sensitivity of this issue, GAO evaluations compare 
proposals to at least two consistent benchmarks that would reflect a 
solvent system. One benchmark illustrates the most that we would expect 
benefits to be, while the other illustrates the least that benefits 
could be. The most that benefits could be would result from restoring 
solvency by increasing taxes but leaving current benefits untouched. We 
call these "promised benefits" because they reflect the benefits 
promised under the existing benefit formula. In contrast, the least 
that benefits could be would result from restoring solvency only 
through benefit reductions and leaving taxes untouched. We call these 
"funded benefits" because they reflect the benefit levels that existing 
revenues would be able to fund. Still, benefits could be reduced in a 
variety of ways under such a benchmark.[Footnote 15]

In particular, the timing of any policy changes in a benchmark scenario 
should be consistent with the proposals against which the benchmark is 
compared. For example, the analysis of most proposals assumes that the 
proposal is enacted fairly soon, usually within a few years. A 
benchmark would be consistent with such a proposal if the timing of its 
policy changes were comparable to the timing of policy changes in the 
proposal. So, for example, it would not be consistent to compare a 
proposal that takes effect soon with a benchmark whose policy changes 
do not take effect for many years. 

[SECTION II NOTES]

[1] This and all subsequent estimates are from the 2005 Trustees' 
Report and reflect the intermediate assumptions. Because the future is 
uncertain, the trustees use three alternative sets of assumptions to 
show a range of possible outcomes. The intermediate assumptions 
represent the Social Security Administration's best estimate of the 
trust funds' future financial outlook. The trustees also present 
estimates using low cost and high cost sets of assumptions. 

[2] The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) projects that the Social 
Security trust funds will be able to pay full benefits until 2052. The 
differences between the CBO and the Social Security trustees' estimates 
reflect differences in both economic assumptions and projection 
methodology. The CBO methodology uses a different approach for 
capturing and describing the uncertainty of future outcomes. However, 
both the CBO and the trustees' projections point to the same 
conclusion: that future Social Security deficits will be large and 
growing over the long term. See Congressional Budget Office, The 
Outlook for Social Security. Washington, D.C., June 2004. 

[3] Actuaries call this the open-group unfunded obligation. 

[4] Significant uncertainty surrounds any long-term projection. 
Therefore, the focus should not be on the estimate itself, but rather 
what the estimates can achieve in terms of solvency. 

[5] Actuaries call this the closed-group unfunded obligation. 

[6] Technical Panel on Assumptions and Methods (2003). Report to the 
Social Security Advisory Board. Washington, D.C., October 2003, pp. 84- 
85. This marked a change from the 1965 Advisory Council on Social 
Security, which rejected the issue of an infinite horizon in 
formulating projections. See Advisory Council on Social Security, The 
Status of the Social Security Program and Recommendations for Its 
Improvement, Washington D.C. 1965 at 
http://www.ssa.gov/history/reports/65council/65part1.html. 

[7] Technical Panel on Assumptions and Methods (2003). Report to the 
Social Security Advisory Board. Washington, D.C., October 2003, pp. 87- 
88. 

[8] For more detail about the temporary trust fund buildup and how it 
interacts with the federal budget, see GAO, Social Security Financing: 
Implications of Government Stock Investing for the Trust Fund, the 
Federal Budget, and the Economy, GAO/AIMD/HEHS-98-74 (Washington, D.C.: 
Apr. 22, 1998); GAO, Social Security Reform: Demographic Trends 
Underlie Long-Term Financing Shortage, GAO/T-HEHS-98-43 (Washington, 
D.C.: Nov. 20, 1997). 

[9] GAO has developed a health care framework to help focus attention 
on this important area and to help educate key policy makers and the 
public on the current system and related challenges. GAO's health care 
framework can be found at www.gao.gov/cghome/hccrisis/health.pdf. See 
also GAO, Comptroller General's Forum on Health Care: Unsustainable 
Trends Necessitate Comprehensive and Fundamental Reforms to Control 
Spending and Improve Value, GAO-04-793SP (Washington, D. C.: May 1, 
2004). 

[10] Net interest is primarily interest on debt held by the public but 
also includes interest earned from other sources and interest paid for 
purposes other than borrowing from the public. 

[11] For additional discussion of our budget simulations, see GAO, Our 
Nation's Fiscal Outlook: The Federal Government's Long-Term Budget 
Imbalance, at http://www.gao.gov/special.pubs/long-term/long-term.html. 

[12] Solvency could also be achieved through a combination of tax and 
benefit actions. This would reduce the magnitude of the required change 
in taxes or benefits compared with changes made exclusively to taxes or 
benefits as shown in Figure 15. 

[13] The Social Security Act does not address what would happen if the 
trust funds become exhausted. 

[14] This trust fund exhaustion scenario is intended as an analytic 
tool, not a legal determination. See GAO, Social Security Reform: 
Analysis of a Trust Fund Exhaustion Scenario, GAO-03-907 (Washington, 
D.C.: July 29, 2003). 

[15] For more information about the benchmarks, see app. I of GAO, 
Social Security: Distribution of Benefits and Taxes Relative to 
Earnings Level, GAO-04-747 (Washington, D.C.: June 15, 2004). 

[End of Section II]

III. What are the options for Social Security reform? 

A wide variety of options for reform have been proposed. In providing 
an overview of the possibilities for reform, this section attempts to 
list and describe the range of options individually. However, reform 
proposals generally package several options together, and the various 
options can interact with and tend to balance or offset one another. 
Evaluating complete proposals as packages of various options helps 
capture such interactions. 

Options for reforming Social Security generally fall into three broad 
groups: 

* changing benefits,

* changing revenues, and: 

* changing the program structure with new individual accounts. 

Some of the reform options focus on restoring Social Security's long- 
term solvency. However, a few aim to enhance benefits for specific 
groups, such as widows and low earners who are especially at risk of 
poverty. Often, such enhancements are packaged along with benefit 
reductions for middle and higher level earners. Also, changing the 
structure of the program with individual accounts will not, by 
themselves, achieve solvency. Such approaches generally aim to help 
move the program toward funding benefit promises in advance and giving 
individuals the possibility to earn higher returns on their 
contributions. Since the individual accounts do not result in 
sustainable solvency, they are often packaged with other benefit 
reduction or revenue enhancement options that as a package do achieve 
sustainable solvency. 

CHANGING BENEFITS: 

1. What are ways of changing the benefit formula? 

As described in section 1, Social Security uses a multifaceted formula 
to determine initial benefits. This formula can be modified in various 
ways, either to reduce benefits or to enhance benefits for particular 
beneficiaries. 

Such ways include: 

* Changing the factors in the formula that determine what percentage of 
each worker's average monthly lifetime earnings are replaced. The 
current benefit formula replaces 90 percent of average indexed earnings 
up to a certain dollar threshold, 32 percent of average indexed 
earnings above that threshold and below a second threshold, and 15 
percent of average indexed earnings above the second threshold (see 
Fig. 16). These replacement percentages could be reduced in a variety 
of amounts and combinations. Also, additional thresholds could be 
added, and different replacement percentages would apply to the new 
segments of average earnings that result from the new thresholds. 

Figure 16: Social Security Benefit Formula Replaces Earnings at 
Different Rates: 

[See PDF for image] -graphic text: 

Line graph with 71 items. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $0;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $0. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $100;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $90. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $200;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $180. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $300;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $270. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $400;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $360. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $500;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $450. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $600;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $540. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $700;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $587.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $800;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $619.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $900;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $651.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1000;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $683.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1100;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $715.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1200;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $747.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1300;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $779.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1400;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $811.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1500;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $843.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1600;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $875.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1700;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $907.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1800;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $939.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $1900;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $971.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2000;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1003.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2100;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1035.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2200;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1067.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2300;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1099.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2400;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1131.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2500;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1163.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2600;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1195.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2700;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1227.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2800;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1259.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $2900;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1291.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3000;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1323.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3100;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1355.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3200;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1387.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3300;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1419.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3400;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1451.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3500;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1483.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3600;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1515.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3700;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1547.66. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3800;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1576.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $3900;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1591.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4000;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1606.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4100;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1621.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4200;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1636.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4300;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1651.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4400;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1666.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4500;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1681.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4600;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1696.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4700;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1711.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4800;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1726.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $4900;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1741.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5000;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1756.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5100;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1771.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5200;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1786.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5300;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1801.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5400;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1816.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5500;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1831.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5600;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1846.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5700;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1861.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5800;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1876.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $5900;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1891.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6000;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1906.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6100;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1921.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6200;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1936.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6300;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1951.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6400;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1966.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6500;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1981.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6600;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $1996.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6700;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $2011.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6800;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $2026.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $6900;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $2041.09. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings: $7000;
Monthly benefit amount (2005 dollars): $2056.09. 

Source: Social Security Administration. 

[End of figure]

* Indexing the lifetime earnings used in the formula by prices instead 
of wages. Under the current formula, the determination of initial 
benefits includes a calculation of the worker's total covered earnings 
received over his or her lifetime, indexed or corrected for the growth 
in wages over that time period. In the past, wages have grown faster 
than prices and are expected to continue to be greater than increases 
in prices in the future as well. Indexing to prices rather than wages, 
commonly implemented by modifying the replacement percentages, would 
reduce benefits. In practical terms, doing so would result in a 
proportional benefit reduction across all earnings levels. However, 
this could also be formulated in a progressive manner, where only those 
individuals above a certain income level would be subject to price 
indexing. 

* Indexing the benefit formula to reflect improvements in longevity. If 
people live longer in retirement and collect benefits for more years, 
the cost of those benefits increases. Indexing the benefit formula to 
reflect improvements in the average life span of the population could 
be used to keep the cost of lifetime benefits the same as people live 
longer. Indexing benefits to such improvements in longevity would be 
similar to increasing the full retirement age, as workers would have to 
retire at an older age to get the same benefit as they would under the 
current full retirement age. In practical terms, modifying the benefit 
formula in this manner would result in a proportional benefit reduction 
across all earnings levels. 

* Changing the number of working years over which annual earnings are 
averaged. Under the current benefit formula, the calculation of the 
worker's total covered earnings received over his or her lifetime is 
based on the highest 35 years of that worker's earnings. Since many 
workers have earnings in more that 35 years, the current formula 
permits a higher benefit because workers are able to exclude their 
lowest earning years from this calculation. Including more of these 
lower-earning years into the calculation would reduce the average 
lifetime earnings, which, in turn, would reduce benefits as compared to 
current levels. On the other hand, decreasing the number of years used 
in the benefit formula, for example, to exclude years when women are 
out of the labor force having children, would eliminate additional 
years in which they had lower or no earnings, and in turn increase 
benefits for these workers. 

* Modifying factors used to determine benefits for spouses and 
widow(er)s. Under the current system, widows or widowers receive 
benefits that can vary from 50 to 67 percent of the benefit the couples 
received while both spouses were living, depending on the work records 
of both spouses. The percentage of the worker's benefit that spouses 
and widow(er)s receive could be altered to boost the benefits of 
widow(er)s, who are at especially high risk of poverty. 

* Reintroducing minimum benefit amounts. Before 1981, Social Security 
had minimum benefit levels. Some proposals would establish new 
minimums, for example, for workers who work a certain number of years 
with earnings greater than or equal to the minimum wage. This would be 
a benefit increase targeting lower earners, who are at especially high 
risk of poverty. 

* Modifying adjustments for early or delayed retirement. Currently, 
benefits are reduced for workers who retire before the full retirement 
age and increased for those who retire after that age. These 
adjustments could be modified to reduce benefits even more for workers 
who retire before the full retirement age or increase benefits more for 
those who delay retirement. 

2. How could COLAs be reduced? 

Each year, monthly benefits being paid out are increased to keep pace 
with inflation using a cost-of-living adjustment (COLA). The COLA is 
based on the consumer price index (CPI). Studies have found that the 
CPI overstates the true rate of inflation, which would make these COLAs 
higher than necessary to keep pace with inflation.[Footnote 1] Any such 
errors in COLAs can be especially expensive since they have a 
cumulative effect. For the same reason, the effect of changes increases 
as beneficiaries age. COLA reductions would reduce estimated future 
benefit costs immediately, and they would affect both current and 
future beneficiaries. COLAs could also be used simply to reduce 
benefits, as for example, lowering the COLA to less than the CPI, 
limiting the COLA to a specified threshold, or delaying the COLA. 

3. How would increasing the retirement age work? 

Social Security pays full benefits at the full retirement age. Until 
recently, the full retirement age was 65. Under reforms enacted in 
1983, the full retirement age is gradually increasing to 67. Workers 
are eligible to start receiving retirement benefits at age 62, but the 
benefits are reduced because workers retiring early receive their 
monthly benefits for more years. Workers who retire after the full 
retirement age receive a credit that increases their monthly benefits 
because they receive benefits over fewer years. 

One option for reform would be to increase the full retirement age 
further. Doing so has the effect of reducing benefits proportionally 
across all earnings levels. For any given age at which a worker 
retires, their benefits will be lower than if the full retirement age 
had not been increased. However, an increase in the full retirement age 
could increase disability applications, especially workers in certain 
occupations (e.g., construction) who may not be able to work longer. 

Another option would be to increase the earliest eligibility age. 
However, if no changes were made to the full retirement age and early 
retirement adjustments, lifetime benefits for those reaching the new 
early retirement age would not be affected significantly. Some workers 
who would have retired before age 65, however, may still qualify for 
Social Security under the Disability Insurance program. 

CHANGING REVENUES: 

4. What are the options for increasing tax revenues? 

There are a variety of options for increasing tax revenues, most of 
which can be done independently or together as part of a package. These 
options include: 

* Raising the Social Security payroll tax rate. Until 1978, raising 
revenues by increasing the OASDI payroll tax rate paid by workers and 
their employers occurred quite regularly.[Footnote 2] The 1977 
amendments to the Social Security Act raised the OASDI rate for workers 
and employers to 6.2 percent, effective in 1990. The 1983 amendments 
increased the payroll tax rate for the self-employed, raising it to 
12.4 percent by 1990. No future increases are scheduled. 

* Raising the cap on taxable earnings. In 2005, earnings above $90,000 
are not subject to payroll taxes. This amount increases each year to 
keep pace with the growth in average wages. If the cap was raised and 
the benefit formula remained the same, workers with earnings above the 
old cap would ultimately receive somewhat higher benefits as well as 
pay more taxes. 

* Covering all employment. Today, Social Security covers and collects 
payroll taxes from about 96 percent of the workforce. 

The vast majority of the remaining uncovered workers are state, local, 
and federal government employees.[Footnote 3] Covering all the 
remaining workers increases revenues relatively quickly and improves 
solvency for some time, since most of the newly covered workers would 
not receive benefits for many years. In the long run, however, benefit 
payments would increase as the newly covered workers started to collect 
benefits. Overall, this change would still represent a net gain for 
solvency, although it would be small. 

5. Are there other ways to increase Social Security's revenues? 

Social security can obtain revenues from sources currently outside of 
the program. These include: 

* Transferring revenues from the Treasury's general fund. General 
revenue transfers could partially fund the system with money from other 
government revenue sources. Such transfers would ultimately be financed 
either by reducing other government spending, increasing taxes, or 
borrowing from the public. 

* Adding a new revenue stream. A new revenue source could be earmarked 
for Social Security, as was done by the 1983 amendments, which extended 
the income tax to a portion of Social Security benefits for higher 
income beneficiaries and earmarked the funds for Social Security. 

* Increasing the investment returns on Social Security holdings. 

Currently, by law, the trust funds are invested in Treasury securities 
that earn a relatively low, safe rate of return. Investing a portion of 
Social Security trust funds in private sector securities could increase 
investment returns but also increase investment risk.[Footnote 4] Under 
a new system of individual accounts that draw from Social Security 
contributions, individuals could also invest in the stock market, 
potentially increasing investment returns while assuming increased 
investment risk. 

CHANGING THE PROGRAM'S STRUCTURE WITH INDIVIDUAL ACCOUNTS: 

Some reform advocates have suggested the use of individual investment 
accounts as a component of Social Security reform. Individual accounts 
are usually associated with two key elements: advance-funding of 
retirement income through investment in private financial assets, 
greater individual control of decisions about investing those assets, 
and individuals assuming the risk associated with such investments. 
Depending on the proposal, these accounts would replace part of the 
current Social Security benefit or they would supplement it. A system 
of individual accounts, especially if they replace a part of the Social 
Security benefit, would constitute a fundamental change to Social 
Security and could be significantly larger than any existing retirement 
investment program. In addition to the question of how to administer 
and manage the accounts, provisions of individual account proposals can 
be grouped in three categories corresponding to different phases of the 
life of the accounts: 

* Contribution phase: This includes the decision of whether to 
participate in the accounts at all, how much is contributed to the 
accounts, and where the contributions come from. 

* Accumulation phase: This includes how account assets are invested and 
built up and whether the benefits from the accounts are guaranteed to 
match the current system. 

* Distribution phase: This includes how account balances are drawn down 
and whether funds can be accessed before retirement for any reason. 

6. Who would manage the accounts? 

A system of individual accounts would require administrative, 
investment and record-keeping tasks covering all three phases of the 
life of each account. These tasks could be performed in a system that 
ranges from very centralized to very decentralized, with varying levels 
of involvement by government agencies, employers, financial 
institutions, and individuals. An example of a largely centralized 
system is the Thrift Savings Plan, which is a retirement savings plan 
for federal employees, including members of the Congress. An example of 
a largely decentralized system is the existing system of individual 
retirement accounts (IRAs), which are tax-deductible individual 
accounts for individuals. 

7. Would accounts be required for Social Security participants? 

The first step in the contribution phase of an individual account 
system would be to determine who participates in the accounts. Some 
proposals would make participation mandatory, while others would make 
it voluntary. Voluntary systems further vary depending on whether 
workers have a onetime choice to participate or can opt in and opt out 
more than once over their careers. In general, greater choice would 
involve greater complexity and cost. [Footnote 5] For example, 
voluntary plans sometimes offer incentives to participate, while 
mandatory plans do not need them. Voluntary plans would also require 
greater educational efforts to help workers make informed choices about 
choosing whether and to what extent to participate. 

8. How much would go into the accounts? 

An individual account plan can provide for contributions in a variety 
of ways. For example, a plan might set contributions at a fixed rate, 
such as 2 percent of pay, or allow a range of rates up to a certain 
dollar amount. Some proposals provide for greater average contribution 
rates for lower earners than for higher earners. For example, 
contribution rates may go down gradually as earnings rise, or 
alternatively, all workers might pay a fixed percentage but have a 
dollar cap on contribution amounts. Also, contributions might be 
collected and deposited by the government in a centralized process or 
by employers or account providers in a decentralized process. 

9. What's the difference between an add-on and a carve-out account? 

Individual accounts can either supplement the current Social Security 
program (add-on) or substitute for all or part of it (carve- 
out).[Footnote 6] With add-on accounts, the account and contributions 
to it have no effect on the Social Security benefit but would require 
contributions and would offer benefits in addition to the current 
Social Security program. With carve-out accounts, the Social Security 
benefit is reduced (or offset) in some way to account for contributions 
that have been carved out, or diverted, from the current Social 
Security program. The accounts then offer the potential for making up 
for or exceeding that offset. 

10. What are transition costs? 

Under various proposals, contributions to the new accounts could come 
from either existing payroll tax revenues, increased contribution 
rates, or general revenue transfers. 

In the case of carve-out accounts, however, existing payroll taxes are 
not adequate to pay for promised Social Security benefits, much less 
for new account contributions. Making account deposits while also 
meeting current benefit costs requires additional revenue, which we 
refer to as transition costs. Depending on the underlying assumptions 
and the specifics of the proposals, these costs generally range from 
less than $1 trillion to more than $2 trillion over the next 75 years, 
in today's dollars. Typically, proposals finance these transition costs 
with general revenue transfers elsewhere in the budget. In turn, 
general revenue transfers require decreased government spending, 
increased revenues, or increased borrowing from the public. Eventually 
the system becomes stable and there are no more transition costs. 
However, this could be many years in the future. 

Under an add-on account plan, transition costs would not be an issue 
because no resources are diverted from paying current benefits, though 
such plans do require additional contributions. These additional 
contributions could come from an increase in the payroll tax, directly 
from individuals or from general revenue. 

11. What investment options would there be? 

With respect to the accumulation phase, individual account plans have 
provisions regarding the range of investment choices participants have. 

Some proposals allow individuals wide latitude in investment options; 
others provide a narrower choice, generally between stock and bond 
mutual funds, and particular types of mutual funds.[Footnote 7] For 
example, the federal government's Thrift Savings Plan permits federal 
employees to choose among five different investment options, including 
Treasury bonds, a corporate bond index fund, an equities index fund, an 
international and small business index options. 

12. How would participants draw on the accounts for retirement income? 

With respect to the distribution phase, individual account systems 
generally use three basic ways to pay retirement benefits: 
annuitization, timed withdrawals, and lump sum payments. Under a system 
of annuities, retirees would receive monthly payments for an agreed- 
upon length of time, and the size of those payments would depend on the 
total value of the individual accounts. Under individual account 
proposals, annuities would be obtained either through government 
agencies or the private market. Some proposals would make annuitization 
mandatory to help ensure that the accounts provided retirement income 
for the entire remaining lifetimes of participants. 

Other options for the payout of accounts include timed withdrawals 
(also referred to as self-annuitization) and lump sum payments. In a 
timed withdrawal, retirees specify a withdrawal schedule with the 
investment manager or record keeper. Each month, they receive their 
predetermined amount, while the balance of the individual account 
remains invested. Under a lump sum payment option, individuals may 
liquidate their accounts through a single payment at retirement and 
choose to spend or save their money according to their needs or 
desires. 

13. Would participants have any guarantee of doing better than under 
the current system? 

To address concerns individuals may have about investment risk, some 
individual account plans offer guarantees that benefits will reach a 
certain level. Under a voluntary approach, such guarantees are intended 
to encourage participation. However, even some mandatory plans have 
offered guarantees. Guarantees can take a variety of forms. For 
example, some proposals would guarantee that Social Security 
beneficiaries would receive total monthly benefits--the traditional 
benefit plus the account--at least as high as those currently 
promised.[Footnote 8] Some other nations with an individual account 
feature in their national pension systems provide for a more minimal 
guarantee on their accounts. Germany, for example, requires that 
account providers return to participants on withdrawal an amount at 
least equal to the nominal[Footnote 9] contributions participants made 
to their accounts. [Footnote 10]

[SECTION III NOTES]

[1] For more information on the CPI and how it overstates the true rate 
of inflation, see Advisory Commission to Study the Consumer Price 
Index, "Toward a More Accurate Measure of the Cost of Living," Final 
Report to the Senate Committee on Finance, Dec. 1996; Brent R. Moulton, 
"Bias in the Consumer Price Index: What Is the Evidence?," Journal of 
Economic Perspectives, Vol. 10, No. 4, 1996, pp. 159-177; Congressional 
Budget Office, Is the Growth of the CPI a Biased Measure of Changes in 
the Cost of Living? (Washington, D.C., 1994). 

[2] The OASDI tax rate was initially set at 1 percent of the first 
$3,000 of earnings for both the employee and the employer. The rate 
increased 20 times between 1937, when the tax was first collected, and 
1990, when the rate reached its current level. Higher rates were not 
needed early in the program, when relatively few of the elderly 
qualified for benefits. The tax rate increases were always anticipated 
as part of the maturing of the pay-as-you-go program. 

[3] About one-fourth of public employees do not pay Social Security 
taxes on the earnings from their government jobs. Extending Social 
Security's coverage to include them could result in potentially 
significant transition costs for some of their state and local 
government employers. See GAO, Social Security: Implications of 
Extending Mandatory Coverage to State and Local Government Employees, 
GAO/HEHS-98-196 (Washington, D.C.: Aug. 18, 1998). 

[4] GAO, Social Security Financing: Implications of Government Stock 
Investing for the Trust Fund, the Federal Budget, and the Economy, GAO/ 
AIMD/HEHS-98-74 (Washington, D.C.: Apr. 22, 1998). 

[5] GAO, Social Security Reform: Information on Using a Voluntary 
Approach to Individual Accounts, GAO-03-309 (Washington, D.C.: Mar. 10, 
2003). 

[6] In GAO's work to date, we have used the term "add-on" accounts to 
refer to accounts that would have no effect on Social Security 
benefits, would supplement those benefits, and would draw contributions 
from new revenue streams. In contrast, we have used the term "carve- 
out" accounts to refer to accounts that would result in some reduction 
or offset to Social Security benefits because contributions to those 
accounts would draw on existing Social Security revenues. Others have 
used these terms in different manners. For example, some have used "add-
ons" in connection with new individual accounts funded from new revenue 
sources that result in a reduction or offset to some or all Social 
Security benefits. In the final analysis, there are two key dimensions: 
first, whether individual accounts are funded from existing or new 
revenue sources; second, whether individual accounts result in some 
reduction or offset to Social Security benefits. 

[7] Mutual funds pool the limited funds of small investors into large 
amounts, thereby gaining the advantages of large-scale trading. 
Investors are assigned a prorated share of the total funds according to 
the size of their investments. 

[8] See GAO, Social Security Reform: Information on the Archer-Shaw 
Proposal, GAO/AIMD/HEHS-00-56 (Washington, D.C.: Jan. 18, 2000); GAO, 
Social Security: Reform Proposals Could Have a Variety of Effects on 
Distribution of Benefits and Payroll Taxes, GAO-04-872T (Washington, 
D.C.: June 15, 2004). 

[9] This amount is not adjusted for inflation; rather it is just the 
dollar amount the individual contributed. 

[10] For more information on the international experience with 
individual accounts, including Germany, see GAO, Social Security 
Reform: Information on Using a Voluntary Approach to Individual 
Accounts, GAO-03-309 (Washington, D.C.: Mar. 10, 2003). 

[End of Section III]

IV. What are the implications of Social Security Reform? 

CHANGING BENEFITS OR REVENUE: 

1. What will achieving sustainable solvency require? 

Restoring solvency for the long term requires that either Social 
Security gets additional income (revenue increases), reduces costs 
(benefit reductions), or undertakes some combination of the two. The 
sooner action is taken, the smaller the magnitude of changes that will 
be necessary to achieve solvency. If changes were enacted today, 
achieving solvency would require either benefit reductions of 13 
percent or tax increases of 15 percent. If no changes were made until 
2041--the year the trust funds are estimated to be exhausted--achieving 
solvency for the period 2041 through 2079 would require reductions in 
benefits of 29 percent or increases in taxes of 41 percent. Funding the 
current system of scheduled benefits and taxes over the next 75 years 
would require $4 trillion today.[Footnote 1] While it is possible to 
make the system solvent over a 75-year period, doing so does not solve 
the problem. It only ensures that projected revenues equal projected 
outlays over the 75-year period. Solutions that lead to sustainable 
solvency are those that avoid the need to periodically revisit this 
difficult issue.[Footnote 2]

2. What effects do these options have on the overall federal budget and 
the public debt? 

Social Security reforms will affect the amount of cash necessary to pay 
benefits. These cash requirements ultimately determine the effects on 
federal budget deficits and the public debt. Regardless of the value of 
government securities in the trust funds, benefits are paid in cash. 
When Social Security's cash revenues are not sufficient to pay 
benefits, the trust funds will exchange government securities for 
enough cash to cover all promised benefits. Treasury will need to find 
that cash from decreased spending in the rest of the budget, increased 
revenues, additional government borrowing from the public, or some 
combination thereof. Additional government borrowing from the public 
increases the unified budget deficit and the public debt.[Footnote 3]

3. Can Social Security reforms promote economic growth and worker 
productivity? 

As more people live longer in retirement, the costs of providing 
retirement income will increase unless people retire later or collect 
smaller benefits. At the same time, relatively fewer workers will be 
producing the goods and services consumed by all. In the final 
analysis, no matter what shape Social Security reforms take, those 
workers will need to be more productive to keep up with the demand for 
goods and services or we will need more workers. Ideally, Social 
Security reforms would indirectly promote economic growth and worker 
productivity, by reducing the strain on the budget. Reduced budgetary 
pressure could increase national saving and allow greater spending on 
education, plants, and equipment to make workers more productive. 

4. How would benefit reductions affect the adequacy of benefits? 

The Social Security program has played an important role in helping 
ensure adequate incomes for its beneficiaries. One means of addressing 
Social Security's solvency issue is to reduce benefits from those 
promised by today's program. Benefits can be reduced in many different 
ways, but regardless of the approach, benefit reductions will affect 
the adequacy of benefits. However, certain approaches can have a bigger 
impact on the adequacy of benefits for particular groups of 
beneficiaries. For example, some benefit reductions take a proportional 
approach, reducing benefit formula factors at the same rate across all 
earnings levels. In contrast, some approaches would reduce benefits 
less for low earners than for high earners. Also, some proposals 
enhance benefits for low earners in combination with proportional 
reductions. The choice of benefit reduction approaches will affect the 
adequacy of income in the future. A proportional benefit reduction 
approach would have a greater number of retired workers with benefits 
below the official poverty threshold than under a non-proportional 
benefit reduction approach of equal financial magnitude. 

The effects of some reform options parallel those of benefit reductions 
made through the benefit formula. For example, if workers were to 
retire at a given age, an increase in Social Security's full retirement 
age would result in a reduction in monthly benefits; moreover, that 
benefit reduction would be a proportional reduction. Another example 
would be indexing the benefit formula to prices instead of wages, as is 
currently done, or indexing benefits to future increases in life 
expectancy. Such changes would also be proportional reductions because 
all earnings levels would be treated the same under each approach. 

A consequence of changing to price indexing could be that Social 
Security benefits may not keep pace with improvements in the society's 
standard of living. When wages grow faster than prices, workers can 
afford to consume more goods and services, their purchasing power 
increases, and the standard of living improves. Historically, wages 
have grown faster than prices, on average. Since Social Security's 
current benefit formula is indexed to wages, increases in initial 
benefits keep pace with improvements in the standard of living. 
Indexing benefits to prices instead of wages would make the purchasing 
power of benefits remain constant even if wage growth were improving 
purchasing power for the rest of society. In 1960, the standard of 
living was much lower than it is today. In that year, the average 
monthly benefit for all retired workers was $74.04. If the average 
monthly benefit in 2005 were the same, adjusted for inflation, it would 
be $483.51. If it were adjusted for wage growth instead, the $483.51 
would be $676.26 today. 

5. Does greater progressivity in benefits imply greater income 
adequacy? 

To help ensure that beneficiaries have adequate incomes, Social 
Security's benefit formula is designed to be progressive, that is, to 
provide disproportionately larger benefits, as a percentage of 
earnings, to lower earners than to higher earners. However, greater 
progressivity is not the same thing as greater adequacy. Under some 
reform options, Social Security could distribute benefits more 
progressively than current law yet provide lower, less adequate 
benefits.[Footnote 4] At the same time, reform provisions that favor 
lower earners can offset other provisions that disfavor them. As a 
result, any evaluations should consider a proposal's provisions taken 
together as a whole. 

6. What would happen to the adequacy of benefits for the disabled, 
dependents, and survivors? 

Social Security has substantially improved income adequacy for specific 
subgroups of beneficiaries, such as minorities, women, single persons, 
widows, and the disabled. However, even with those improvements, 
significant levels of poverty remain, reflecting the generally lower 
lifetime earnings and reduced access to other sources of retirement 
income among such groups. A reform proposal's effect on adequacy for 
subgroups of beneficiaries will depend on how it changes benefits for 
these subgroups. Many proposals make changes to the overall benefit 
structure but do not protect various subgroups. Therefore, a provision 
that reduces benefits for retirees generally would, in many cases, also 
reduce benefits for individuals with disabilities. However, the 
circumstances facing disabled workers differ from those facing retired 
workers. For example, DI beneficiaries enter the program at younger 
ages than other beneficiaries and remain in the program in most cases 
until death. Thus, if the COLA was reduced, disabled beneficiaries 
could be subject to reductions in benefits for many more years than 
retirees, due to the cumulative effect of the COLA. Some proposals also 
include features that might enhance benefits for specific subgroups, 
such as low-income workers and surviving spouses, which can have 
substantial improvements on their income adequacy. 

7. How will individual equity be affected by these reform options? 

The equity perspective focuses on whether, over their lifetimes, 
beneficiaries can expect to receive a fair return on their 
contributions; essentially whether or not they get their money's worth 
from the system. By linking benefits to a worker's earnings through his 
or her payroll tax contributions, Social Security also incorporates the 
principle of individual equity. One can assess proposals for their 
effect on individual equity, although in some cases this can be 
difficult. For proposals where the financing of the reform is well 
defined, for example, an increase in the payroll tax, equity can be 
assessed through looking at measures like the ratio of expected 
benefits received to expected taxes paid. 

In other cases, assessing a proposal for its effect on individual 
equity can be more difficult, as, for example, when reform options 
involve general revenue transfers. Such proposals typically do not 
specify how such transfers are to be financed or who will eventually 
bear their burden, yet general revenue transfers implicitly require 
future tax increases, spending cuts in other parts of the budget, or a 
combination of both, all of which have substantial distributional 
consequences. Without knowing who will bear the costs of financing 
these transfers, the equity perspective cannot accurately determine how 
well lower earners will fare relative to higher earners in a given 
system or across proposed reforms. 

8. What issues would arise in implementing these options? 

Some degree of implementation and administrative complexity arises in 
virtually all proposed changes to Social Security. However, regardless 
of whether policy makers raise taxes or reduce benefits, or agree upon 
a combination of these two approaches, how readily the changes can be 
explained to the public and the amount of time individuals are given to 
respond to the changes are important issues. A reasonable amount of 
time will be required for the general public to readily understand the 
financing and benefit structure of any changes. Individuals may also 
need time to make adjustments to their retirement decisions based on 
these changes. For example, individuals may decide they need to work 
longer, and this decision may necessitate a career change. Therefore, 
an education effort may be needed in order to increase public 
confidence and avoid expectations gaps. 

CHANGING THE PROGRAM'S STRUCTURE WITH INDIVIDUAL ACCOUNTS: 

9. Would individual accounts help achieve solvency? 

There are many different ways that an individual account system could 
be set up. However, individual accounts, whether voluntary or 
mandatory, or whether structured as add-on benefits or as a carve-out 
from the current system, would generally not by themselves achieve 
solvency. Achieving solvency requires more revenue, lower benefits, or 
both. Add-on accounts generally have no effect on the current Social 
Security benefit or the financing of the system and, thus, have no 
direct effect on solvency. Because carve out accounts have a negative 
effect on solvency, as compared with the status quo, most proposals 
creating such accounts bundle them together with a variety of other 
reform provisions, and it is the other provisions that reduce benefits 
or increase revenues that effectively achieve solvency. Thus, the role 
of individual accounts in reform plans is generally not so much to 
achieve solvency for the current system as to offer workers an 
opportunity to make up for the benefit reductions or other changes that 
are included as part of the whole proposal. Depending on their design, 
individual accounts can contribute to sustainability, by providing a 
mechanism to pre-fund retirement benefits that would be immune to 
demographic booms and busts. However, if these accounts are financed 
through borrowing, pre-funding will not be achieved until the 
additional debt has been repaid, which is likely not to happen for many 
decades. 

10. What would it cost to create a system with individual accounts? 

Reform proposals with individual accounts would require substantial 
additional revenues for a significant period after they are started. 
This is because existing payroll taxes would be used both to finance 
the new accounts and to pay benefits. These so-called transition costs 
are very large; for example, they have been estimated at over $1 
trillion for some recent plans over 75 years.[Footnote 5] A variety of 
approaches can be used to finance these transition costs, but all 
involve generating cash revenue to deposit into the accounts. Some 
proposals fund the transition costs with transfers from the general 
fund of the Treasury, and such transfers are also known as general 
revenue transfers. However, these revenues have to come from somewhere, 
either from reducing other government spending, increasing revenues, 
borrowing from the public, or some combination thereof. 

In the long run, however, the transition costs may be repaid and the 
net cost of the accounts to the system might be zero, depending on the 
design of the plan. With carve out individual account proposals, 
workers choosing to participate in the accounts have their benefits 
reduced to reflect the value of the contributions made to their 
accounts. These benefit offsets could be a mechanism to pay back the 
transition costs eventually, but that cost recovery comes many years 
after the outflow required for the transition. 

11. Aren't these transition costs less than the cost of fixing the 
current system? 

While the previously mentioned transition costs for individual accounts 
fully fund the accounts, they do not assure solvency of the existing 
system. In addition to those transition costs, a combination of 
additional benefit reductions or revenue increases would still be 
required to restore 75-year solvency for the existing system. 

12. What effect would individual accounts have on national saving? 

The effect that individual accounts have on national saving depends on 
how the accounts are financed. Individual account proposals that fund 
accounts through redirection of payroll taxes or general revenue do not 
increase national saving directly. The redirection of payroll taxes or 
general revenue reduces government saving by the same amount that the 
individual accounts increase private saving. Individual accounts 
financed through a new revenue source, such as increasing payroll 
taxes, could increase national saving. Beyond these direct effects, the 
actual net effect of a proposal on national saving is difficult to 
estimate because of uncertainties in predicting changes in future 
spending and revenue policies of the government as well as changes in 
the saving behavior of private households and individuals. For example, 
the higher deficits that result from redirecting payroll taxes to 
individual accounts could prompt changes in fiscal policy that reduce 
spending or increase revenue thereby resulting in lower deficits than 
would otherwise have been the case and increase net national saving. On 
the other hand, households may respond by reducing their other saving 
in response to the creation of individual accounts. No expert consensus 
exists on how Social Security reform proposals would affect the saving 
behavior of private households and businesses. 

13. How would individual accounts affect the adequacy of benefits? 

Individual accounts have the potential for a higher rate of return on 
contributions than is available in the current system. Along with this 
potential higher rate of return comes increased risk. Thus, while 
individual accounts by themselves may improve the adequacy of benefits, 
it is also possible that individual accounts will worsen the adequacy 
of benefits. However, since individual accounts do not achieve solvency 
on their own, they are typically packaged with other options that 
reduce benefits or increase revenues, and it is these options that 
achieve solvency. As stated previously, the role of individual accounts 
in reform proposals is generally to offer workers an opportunity to 
make up for the benefit reductions or other changes that are included 
as part of the entire proposal. Therefore, the overall impact that 
individual accounts have on the adequacy of benefits will depend on the 
structure of the accounts, the other changes included in the reform 
proposal, the choices made by the individual, and the performance of 
the assets in the account. 

14. What effect would individual accounts have on the adequacy of 
benefits for the disabled, dependents, and survivors? 

The effect on adequacy of benefits for subgroups of beneficiaries will 
depend on factors unique to each subgroup, as well as the structure of 
the individual accounts. Depending on their design, individual accounts 
will have a varying effect on the adequacy of benefits for subgroups of 
beneficiaries. Under some proposals, individual accounts are likely to 
be a bequeathable asset, which may have a significant effect on the 
benefits of dependents and survivors. In most cases, disabled 
beneficiaries leave the workforce sooner than retired workers. With 
fewer years to make contributions and accrue interest, disabled 
beneficiaries will likely have smaller account balances. While disabled 
beneficiaries will still receive a monthly disability benefit, some 
proposals do not allow access to income from individual accounts until 
an individual reaches retirement age. 

15. What issues would arise in implementing individual accounts? 

Regardless of how the individual accounts are structured, how readily 
the accounts can be implemented, administered, and explained to the 
public are important issues. Implementation issues that would need to 
be addressed would include, for example, the management of the 
information and money flow needed to maintain such a system, the degree 
of choice and flexibility individuals would have over investment 
options and access to their accounts, investment education and 
transitional efforts, and the methods and mechanisms that would be used 
to pay out benefits upon retirement. These and other changes will 
require time and funds for implementation in order to achieve 
reasonable administrative costs. As with any changes to Social 
Security, individuals may need time to make adjustments to retirement 
planning. They may also need time to increase their knowledge of 
investments and risk. Implementing a system that includes individual 
accounts would also raise a number of issues, such as those regarding 
the cost of managing accounts and investments, how to manage financial 
flows, and other issues. 

16. What would happen to administrative costs with individual accounts? 

The cost of administering a system with individual accounts is likely 
to be higher than the administrative costs of the current system, and 
this cost could reduce the amount of savings accumulated in the 
accounts. However, individual accounts would provide greater individual 
choice in retirement investments and would carry the potential for a 
higher rate of return on contributions than is available in the current 
system. Choices regarding account administration and record keeping 
will affect program administrative costs. A centralized system would 
take advantage of economies of scale, which is to say that the more 
accounts you manage, the lower the cost for each; thus it could have 
lower administrative costs than a decentralized system, especially 
considering a number of individuals may initially have small account 
balances. Administrative costs will also be affected by the amount of 
choice individuals have in their investments. When a wide range of 
investment choices is offered, administrative costs are likely to rise. 
This is especially true if the choices include more actively managed 
investments. These investments are accompanied by higher management 
fees because the investment manager spends more time and money on 
researching, selecting, buying, and selling investments. In addition, 
systems that offer individuals the option to frequently transfer funds 
between investments or more choice in payout options can have higher 
administrative costs. Permitting individuals to choose among several 
withdrawal options could increase administrative complexity and cost by 
requiring systems to explain and keep track of the various choices. 

17. What tools and educational efforts would workers need to exercise 
the increased choices associated with individual accounts? 

Individual accounts would require a major, ongoing educational effort 
to help individuals understand the accounts. An essential challenge 
would be to help people understand the relationship between their 
individual accounts and traditional Social Security benefits, thereby 
ensuring that we avoid any gap in expectations about current or future 
benefits. This challenge is even greater if the individual accounts 
were voluntary since individuals would need to make informed 
participation decisions, as well as understand the effect of a benefit 
offset based on participation. Individuals would also need to be 
informed enough to make prudent investment decisions, which would 
require investor education, especially if individual accounts were 
mandatory. For example, individuals would need information on basic 
investment principles, the risks associated with available choices, and 
the effect of choosing among alternatives offered for annuitizing or 
otherwise withdrawing or borrowing accumulations from the accounts. 
This would be especially important for individuals who are unfamiliar 
with making investment choices. 

[SECTION IV NOTES]

[1] Additional revenue, beyond the $4 trillion, would also be required 
in order to repay the bonds in the trust funds. 

[2] Funding the current system fully forever without cutting benefits 
or raising taxes would require $11.1 trillion today. However, this 
would change the financing structure of the system from pay-as-you-go 
to advance funding. 

[3] The unified budget deficit is the amount by which the government's 
on-budget and off-budget outlays exceed the sum of its on-budget and 
off-budget receipts. Public debt is federal debt held by all investors 
outside of the federal government. 

[4] GAO, Social Security: Distribution of Benefits and Taxes Relative 
to Earnings Level, GAO-04-747 (Washington, D.C.: June 15, 2004). 

[5] While this estimate indicates the amount of the transition costs 
over 75-years, it is important to note that the transition costs may be 
repaid and part of this repayment may occur beyond the 75-year period. 
Likewise, if the repayment begins within the 75-year period, this 
estimate may understate the total transition costs. 

[End of Section IV]

Glossary of Key Terms: 

Add-On: Individual accounts that would have no effect on Social 
Security benefits, would supplement those benefits, and would draw 
contributions from new revenue streams. 

Adequacy: (See Income Adequacy.) 

Annuity: An insurance product that provides a stream of payments for a 
pre-established amount of time in return for a premium payment--the 
amount being converted into any annuity. For example, a life annuity 
provides payments for as long as the annuitant lives. Only insurance 
companies can underwrite annuities in the United States. Other 
financial intermediaries, such as banks and stock brokerage firms, may 
sell annuities issued by insurance companies. 

Average Indexed Monthly Earnings (AIME): The average monthly earnings 
received over a worker's career, adjusted yearly by the change in 
national average earnings. It is the dollar amount used to calculate 
Social Security benefits for individuals who attain age 62 or become 
disabled (or die) after 1978. To arrive at the AIME, SSA adjusts a 
person's actual past earnings using an "average wage index," so he or 
she does not lose the value of past earnings in relation to more recent 
earnings. For people who attained age 62 or became disabled (or died) 
before 1978, SSA uses Average Monthly Earnings (AME). 

Baby Boomers: Cohort of Americans born from 1946 through 1964; 76 
million strong, they represent the longest sustained population growth 
in U.S. history. 

Baseline: A measurement that serves as a basis against which all 
following measurements are compared. 

Benchmark: A measurement or standard that serves as a point of 
reference by which process performance is measured. 

Carve-Out: Individual accounts that would result in some reduction or 
offset to Social Security benefits because contributions to those 
accounts would draw on existing Social Security revenues. 

Consumer Price Index (CPI): A measure of the change over time in the 
prices, inclusive of sales and excise taxes, paid by urban households 
for a representative market basket of consumer goods and services. The 
CPI is prepared by the U. S. Department of Labor and used to compute 
COLA increases. 

Contribution and Benefit Base: The cap on taxable earnings used to fund 
Social Security. The cap, also called the taxable maximum wage or 
taxable wage base, limits the earnings that can be used in the benefit 
formula and, therefore, limits the size of benefits. The cap limits the 
program's costs and the payroll taxes that pay for them. Limiting the 
size of benefits reflects the program's role of only providing for a 
floor of protection. In 2005, the cap is $90,000. 

Cost-of-Living Adjustment (COLA): An increase (or decrease) in wages or 
benefits according to the rise (or fall) in the cost-of-living as 
measured by some statistical measure, often the Consumer Price Index 
(CPI). Social Security benefits and Supplemental Security Income 
payments are increased each year to keep pace with increases in the 
cost-of-living (inflation), as measured by the CPI. 

Covered Worker: Workers in covered employment, that is, jobs through 
which the workers have made contributions to Social Security. 

Debt Held by the Public: Federal debt held by all investors outside of 
the federal government, including individuals, corporations, state or 
local governments, the Federal Reserve banking system, and foreign 
governments. When debt held by the Federal Reserve is excluded, the 
remaining amount is referred to as privately held debt. 

Deficit: The amount by which the government's spending exceeds its 
revenues in a given period, usually a fiscal year. The federal deficit 
is the shortfall created when the federal government spends more in a 
fiscal year than it receives in revenues. To cover the shortfall, the 
government sells bonds to the public. 

Defined Benefit: A type of retirement plan that guarantees a specified 
retirement payment at a certain age and after a specified period of 
service. Defined benefit plans promise their participants a steady 
retirement income, generally based on years of service, age at 
retirement, and salary averaged over some number of years. Defined 
benefit plans express benefits as an annuity, but may offer departing 
participants the opportunity to receive lump sum distributions. Defined 
benefit plans are one of two basic types of employer-sponsored pension 
plans. 

Defined Contribution: A type of retirement plan that establishes 
individual accounts for employees to which the employer, participants, 
or both make periodic contributions. Defined contribution plan benefits 
are based on employer and participant contributions to and investment 
returns (gains and losses) on the individual accounts. Employees bear 
the investment risk and often control, at least in part, how their 
individual account assets are invested. Defined contribution plans are 
one of two basic types of employer-sponsored pension plans. 

Dependency Ratio: A rough estimate of the number of dependents per 
worker; generally defined as the ratio of the elderly (ages 65 and 
older) plus the young (under age 15) to the population in the working 
ages (ages 15-64). 

Dependent: A person who is eligible for benefits or care because of his 
or her relationship to an individual. Under the Social Security Act, 
"dependent" means the same as it does for federal income tax purposes; 
i.e., someone for whom the individual is entitled to take a deduction 
on his personal income tax return, generally an individual supported by 
a tax filer for over half of a calendar year. 

Disabled: Disability under Social Security is based on the inability to 
work. SSA considers a person disabled under Social Security rules if 
the person cannot do work that he or she did before and SSA decides 
that the person cannot adjust to other work because of his or her 
medical condition(s). A person's disability must also last or be 
expected to last for at least 1 year or to result in death. Social 
Security program rules assume that working families have access to 
other resources to provide support during periods of short-term 
disabilities, including workers' compensation, insurance, savings, and 
investments. The definition of disability under Social Security is 
different than under other programs. Social Security pays only for 
total long-term disability. No benefits are payable for partial 
disability or for short-term disability. 

Dually Entitled: Workers who qualify for Social Security benefits from 
both their own work and their spouses'. Such workers do not receive 
both the benefits earned as a worker and the full spousal benefit; 
rather, the worker receives the higher amount of the two. 

Early Retirement Age: The age at which individuals qualify for reduced 
retirement benefits if they choose to collect benefits before the 
normal retirement age; the current early retirement age for Social 
Security is 62. Individuals who choose to take retirement benefits 
early will have their monthly benefits permanently reduced, based on 
the number of months they receive checks before they reach full 
retirement age. 

Eligibility: Conditions that must be met for participation. To be 
eligible for Social Security retirement benefits, everyone born in 1929 
or later needs 40 credits. Since a worker can earn 4 credits per year, 
he or she needs at least 10 years of work that is subject to Social 
Security to become eligible for Social Security retirement benefits. 
Each year, the amount of earnings needed for a credit rises as the 
average earnings levels rise. In 2005, a worker receives 1 credit for 
each $920 of earnings, up to the maximum of 4 credits per year. 

Entitlement: A federal program or provision of law that requires 
payments to any person or unit of government that meets the eligibility 
criteria established by law. Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid, and 
veterans' compensation are examples of entitlement programs. 
Entitlements leave no discretion with Congress on how much money to 
appropriate, and some entitlements carry permanent appropriations. 

Equity, including Intergenerational: The goal to ensure that the costs 
and benefits of Social Security bear some relationship to contributions 
and that a much greater burden is not placed on certain specific 
groups, including certain generations of workers. 

Full Retirement Age (FRA): (Also called normal retirement age.) The age 
at which individuals qualify for full, or unreduced, retirement 
benefits from Social Security and employer-sponsored pension plans. The 
normal retirement age for Social Security was 65 for many years. 
Beginning with year 2000 for workers and spouses born 1938 or later and 
widows/ widowers born 1940 or later, the normal retirement age 
increases gradually from age 65 until it reaches age 67 in the year 
2022. 

Fully Funded: A system that is fully funded, or "advance funded," is 
one in which sufficient contributions are put aside each year to pay 
for future benefits when they come due. Defined contribution pensions 
and individual retirement accounts are fully funded by definition. 

General Revenue Transfers: Funds moved from the General Fund of the 
Treasury to other programs, sometimes to maintain the solvency of those 
programs. General funds, constituting about two-thirds of the budget, 
have no direct link between how they are raised and how they are spent. 
General fund receipts include income and excise taxes. 

Gross Domestic Product (GDP): A commonly used measure of domestic 
national income. GDP measures the market value of total output of final 
goods and services produced within a country's territory, regardless of 
the ownership of the factors of production involved, i.e., local or 
foreign, during a given time period, usually a year. Earnings from 
capital invested abroad (mostly interest and dividend receipts) are not 
counted, while earnings on capital owned by foreigners but located in 
the country in question are included. GDP may be expressed in terms of 
product--consumption, investment, government purchases of goods and 
services, and net exports--or it may be expressed in terms of income 
earned-wages, interest, and profits. It is a rough indicator of the 
economic earnings base from which government draws its revenues. 

Hospital Insurance (HI): Also referred to as Part A of Medicare. HI 
provides inpatient hospital care, skilled nursing care home health and 
hospice care subject to a benefit period deductible, and co-payments 
for certain services. 

Income Adequacy: In Social Security's history, "adequacy" has never 
been explicitly defined. However, the Congress expected that Social 
Security benefits would eventually provide more than a "minimal 
subsistence" in retirement for full-time, full-career workers. Various 
measures help examine different aspects of this concept, but no single 
measure can provide a complete picture. Such measures include poverty 
rates, replacement rates, and the proportion of the population that 
depends on others for income support. 

Indexation: (See Price Indexation, Wage Indexation.) 

Individual Equity: The relationship of benefits to contributions; for 
example, implicit rates of return on Social Security contributions or 
money's-worth ratios. 

National Saving: Total saving by all sectors of the economy: personal 
saving, business saving (corporate after-tax profits not paid as 
dividends), and government saving (the budget surplus or deficit-- 
indicating dissaving--of all government entities). National saving 
represents all income not consumed, publicly or privately, during a 
given period. Net national saving is gross national saving less 
consumption of fixed capital (depreciation). 

Off-Budget: Refers to the status of transactions of the government 
(either federal funds or trust funds) that belong on-budget according 
to generally accepted budget concepts, but which are required by law to 
be excluded from the budget. The budget documents routinely report the 
on-budget and off-budget amounts separately and then add them together 
to arrive at the consolidated government totals. 

Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance (OASDI): The two Social 
Security programs--Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) and 
Disability Insurance (DI)--that provide monthly cash benefits to 
beneficiaries and their dependents when the beneficiaries retire, to 
beneficiaries' surviving dependents, and to disabled worker 
beneficiaries and their dependents. 

On-Budget: Refers to transactions that are included within the budget. 

Pay-As-You-Go: System of financing in which contributions that workers 
make in a given year fund the payments to beneficiaries in that same 
year, and the system's trust funds are kept to a relatively small 
contingency reserve. 

Payroll Tax: Tax imposed on some or all of workers' earnings that can 
be imposed on employers, employees, or both. Payroll taxes are used to 
finance the Social Security and Medicare programs. Employers and 
employees each pay Social Security taxes equal to 6.2 percent of all 
employee earnings up to a cap and pay Medicare taxes of 1.45 percent, 
with no cap. Payroll taxes are also known as FICA (Federal Insurance 
Contributions Act) taxes or SECA (Self-Employment Contributions Act), 
if self-employed. 

Poverty: Americans are considered "poor" or "in poverty" if they reside 
in a household with income below the U.S. poverty threshold, as defined 
by the U.S. Office of Management and Budget. Poverty thresholds differ 
by family size and are updated annually for inflation using the 
Consumer Price Index. Median Social Security benefits have historically 
been close to the poverty threshold. Social Security has contributed to 
reducing poverty among the elderly. 

Price Indexation: (Compare Wage Indexation.) A method by which benefits 
are adjusted at periodic intervals by a factor derived from an index of 
prices; one prominent Social Security reform proposal would price-index 
earnings to compute benefits, instead of using wage indexing. Over 
time, increases in wages have been greater and are expected to continue 
to be greater than increases in prices. Indexing earnings to prices 
instead of wages would therefore reduce the average lifetime earnings 
used in the formula, which, in turn, would reduce benefits. 

Primary Insurance Amount (PIA): The monthly amount payable to a retired 
or disabled worker; it is based on a worker's average indexed monthly 
earnings. 

Progressive: Adjusted so that the rate increases as the amount 
increases. Describes a tax in which the rich pay a larger fraction of 
their income than the poor. To help ensure that beneficiaries have 
adequate incomes, Social Security's benefit formula is designed to be 
progressive, that is, to provide disproportionately larger benefits, as 
a percentage of earnings, to lower earners than to higher earners. 

Rate of Return: The gain or loss generated from an investment over a 
specified period of time; also referred to as total return. Calculated 
as the (value now minus value at time of purchase) divided by value at 
time of purchase, expressed as a percentage. In the context of Social 
Security, the implicit rate of return on Social Security contributions 
would be the constant discount rate that equates the present discounted 
value of contributions with the present discounted value of benefits. 

Replacement Rate: The ratio of retirement benefits (from Social 
Security or employer-sponsored plans) to pre-retirement earnings. 
Analysts often compare current benefits to a recipient's previous wages 
to judge the adequacy of Social Security payments. In the context of 
Social Security, the implicit rate of return on Social Security 
contributions would be the constant discount rate that equates the 
present discounted value of contributions with the present discounted 
value of benefits. 

Social Insurance: Under a social insurance program, the society as a 
whole insures its members against various risks they all face, and 
members pay for that insurance at least in part through contributions 
to the system. Social insurance programs, including Social Security, 
are designed to achieve certain social goals. 

Social Security Administration (SSA): The federal agency that 
administers all Social Security-elated programs, including the 
Supplemental Security Income (SSI) and the Disability Insurance (DI) 
programs. 

Solvency: For Social Security, a condition of financial viability in 
which the program can meet its full financial obligations as they come 
due. Specifically, the ability to pay full benefits using existing 
revenue sources and trust fund balances. When a program does not meet 
these conditions, it is said to be insolvent. 

Solvency, Sustainable: For Social Security, to achieve sustainable 
solvency is to maintain the program's solvency beyond Social Security's 
Board of Trustees' 75-year forecast and make Social Security 
permanently solvent. Also defined as having a stable and growing trust 
fund ratio with program revenues increasing faster than outlays at the 
end of the 75-year period. 

Supplemental Security Income (SSI): A federal supplemental income 
program funded by general tax revenues (not Social Security taxes) that 
helps aged, blind, and disabled people who have little or no income, by 
providing monthly cash payments to meet basic needs for food, clothing, 
and shelter. 

Supplementary Medical Insurance (SMI): Medicare SMI, also referred as 
Part B, is a voluntary insurance program that covers physician services 
(in or outside of the hospital), outpatient hospital services, 
ambulatory services, and certain medical supplies and other services, 
for all persons age 65 or older and persons eligible for Part A because 
of disability or chronic renal disease. 

Survivor (Survivor Benefits) After a beneficiary's death, Social 
Security survivor benefits are paid to the beneficiary's survivors, 
which include: 

* the beneficiary's widow/widower age 60 or older, 50 or older if 
disabled, or any age if caring for a child under age 16 or who became 
disabled before age 22;

* the beneficiary's children, if they are unmarried and under age 18, 
under 19 but still in school, or 18 or older but disabled before age 22;

* the beneficiary's parents if the beneficiary provided at least one- 
half of their support. 

A special one-time lump sum payment of $255 may be made to a spouse or 
minor children. An ex-spouse could also be eligible for a widow/ 
widower's benefit on the beneficiary's record. 

Taxable Maximum Wage: (See Contribution and Benefit Base.) 

Taxable Wage Base: (See Contribution and Benefit Base.) 

Transition Costs: Refers to the additional revenue required to 
implement substitute individual account plans. Under some individual 
account plans, portions of Social Security contributions would be 
diverted to the accounts. However, under Social Security's pay-as-you- 
go financing, some of those contributions would also be needed to pay 
for current benefits. Making account deposits while also meeting 
current benefit costs requires additional revenue, which we refer to as 
transition costs. 

Trust Fund: An account, designated as a "trust fund" by law, that is 
credited with income from earmarked collections and charged with 
certain outlays. Collections may come from the public (for example, 
from taxes or user charges) or from intrabudgetary transfers. The 
federal government has more than 150 trust funds. The largest and best- 
known finance major benefit programs (including Social Security and 
Medicare) and infrastructure spending (the Highway and the Airport and 
Airway Trust Funds). These trust funds are essentially sub-accounts of 
the federal government's accounting and budgeting processes. 

Unified Budget: The present form of the budget of the federal 
government in which receipts and outlays from federal funds and trust 
funds are consolidated into a single total. The unified budget includes 
trust fund receipts as income and trust fund payments as expenditures. 
As a result, any Social Security surpluses serve to reduce the overall, 
or unified, federal budget deficit. 

Wage Indexation: (Compare Price Indexation.) A method by which benefits 
are adjusted at periodic intervals. Under its current formula, SSA uses 
the national average wage indexing series to index a person's lifetime 
earnings when computing that person's Social Security benefits. 

[End of Section V]

VI. Related GAO Products: 

Social Security Reform: Early Action Would Be Prudent. GAO-05-397T. 
Washington, D.C.: Mar. 9, 2005. 

Social Security: Distribution of Benefits and Taxes Relative to 
Earnings Level. GAO-04-747. Washington, D.C.: June 15, 2004. 

Social Security Reform: Analysis of a Trust Fund Exhaustion Scenario. 
GAO-03-907. Washington, D.C.: July 29, 2003. 

Social Security: Issues Relating to Noncoverage of Public Employees. 
GAO-03-710T. Washington, D.C.: May 1, 2003. 

Social Security and Minorities: Earnings, Disability Incidence, and 
Mortality Are Key Factors That Influence Taxes Paid and Benefits 
Received. GAO-03-387. Washington, D.C.: Apr. 23, 2003. 

Social Security Reform: Analysis of Reform Models Developed by the 
President's Commission to Strengthen Social Security. GAO-03-310. 
Washington, D.C.: Jan. 15, 2003. 

Social Security Reform: Information on Using a Voluntary Approach to 
Individual Accounts. GAO-03-309. Washington, D.C.: Mar. 10, 2003. 

Social Security: Program's Role in Helping Ensure Income Adequacy. GAO- 
02-62. Washington, D.C.: Nov. 30, 2001. 

Social Security Reform: Potential Effects on SSA's Disability Programs 
and Beneficiaries. GAO-01-35. Washington, D.C.: Jan. 24, 2001. 

Social Security Reform: Information on the Archer-Shaw Proposal. GAO/ 
AIMD/HEHS-00-56. Washington, D.C.: Jan. 18, 2000. 

Social Security: Evaluating Reform Proposals. GAO/AIMD/HEHS-00-29. 
Washington, D.C.: Nov. 4, 1999. 

Social Security Reform: Implications of Raising the Retirement Age. 
GAO/HEHS-99-112. Washington, D.C.: Aug. 27, 1999. 

Social Security: Issues in Comparing Rates of Return with Market 
Investments. GAO/HEHS-99-110. Washington, D.C.: Aug. 5, 1999. 

Social Security: Criteria for Evaluating Social Security Reform 
Proposals. GAO/T-HEHS-99-94. Washington, D.C.: Mar. 25, 1999. 

Social Security: Implications of Extending Mandatory Coverage to State 
and Local Employees. GAO/HEHS-98-196. Washington, D.C.: Aug. 18, 1998. 

Social Security: Different Approaches for Addressing Program Solvency. 
GAO/HEHS-98-33. Washington, D.C.: July 22, 1998. 

Social Security Financing: Implications of Government Stock Investing 
for the Trust Fund, the Federal Budget, and the Economy. GAO/AIMD/ HEHS-
98-74. Washington, D.C.: Apr. 22, 1998. 

Social Security: Restoring Long-Term Solvency Will Require Difficult 
Choices. GAO/T-HEHS-98-95. Washington, D.C.: Feb. 10, 1998. 

[End of section]

GAO's Mission: 

The Government Accountability Office, the investigative arm of 
Congress, exists to support Congress in meeting its constitutional 
responsibilities and to help improve the performance and accountability 
of the federal government for the American people. GAO examines the use 
of public funds; evaluates federal programs and policies; and provides 
analyses, recommendations, and other assistance to help Congress make 
informed oversight, policy, and funding decisions. GAO's commitment to 
good government is reflected in its core values of accountability, 
integrity, and reliability. 

Obtaining Copies of GAO Reports and Testimony: 

The fastest and easiest way to obtain copies of GAO documents at no 
cost is through the Internet. GAO's Web site ( www.gao.gov ) contains 
abstracts and full-text files of current reports and testimony and an 
expanding archive of older products. The Web site features a search 
engine to help you locate documents using key words and phrases. You 
can print these documents in their entirety, including charts and other 
graphics. 

Each day, GAO issues a list of newly released reports, testimony, and 
correspondence. GAO posts this list, known as "Today's Reports," on its 
Web site daily. The list contains links to the full-text document 
files. To have GAO e-mail this list to you every afternoon, go to 
www.gao.gov and select "Subscribe to e-mail alerts" under the "Order 
GAO Products" heading. 

Order by Mail or Phone: 

The first copy of each printed report is free. Additional copies are $2 
each. A check or money order should be made out to the Superintendent 
of Documents. GAO also accepts VISA and Mastercard. Orders for 100 or 
more copies mailed to a single address are discounted 25 percent. 
Orders should be sent to: 

U.S. Government Accountability Office

441 G Street NW, Room LM

Washington, D.C. 20548: 

To order by Phone: 

Voice: (202) 512-6000: 

TDD: (202) 512-2537: 

Fax: (202) 512-6061: 

To Report Fraud, Waste, and Abuse in Federal Programs: 

Contact: 

Web site: www.gao.gov/fraudnet/fraudnet.htm

E-mail: fraudnet@gao.gov

Automated answering system: (800) 424-5454 or (202) 512-7470: 

Public Affairs: 

Jeff Nelligan, managing director,

NelliganJ@gao.gov

(202) 512-4800

U.S. Government Accountability Office,

441 G Street NW, Room 7149

Washington, D.C. 20548: