This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-06-1113T 
entitled 'Business Tax Reform: Simplification and Increased Uniformity 
of Taxation Would Yield Benefits' which was released on September 20, 
2006. 

This text file was formatted by the U.S. Government Accountability 
Office (GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part 
of a longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every 
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of 
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text 
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the 
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided 
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed 
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic 
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail 
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this 
document to Webmaster@gao.gov. 

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work 
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the 
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this 
material separately. 

Testimony: 

Before the Committee on Finance, U.S. Senate: 

United States Government Accountability Office: 

GAO: 

For Release on Delivery Expected at 10:00 a.m. EDT: 

Wednesday, September 20, 2006: 

Business Tax Reform: 

Simplification and Increased Uniformity of Taxation Would Yield 
Benefits: 

Statement of David M. Walker: 

Comptroller General of the United States: 

GAO-06-1113T: 

GAO Highlights: 

Highlights of GAO-06-1113T, a Testimony to the Committee on Finance, 
U.S. Senate 

Why GAO Did This Study: 

Business income taxes, both corporate and noncorporate, are a 
significant portion of federal tax revenue. Businesses also play a 
crucial role in collecting taxes from individuals, through withholding 
and information reporting. However, the design of the current system of 
business taxation is widely seen as flawed. It distorts investment 
decisions, hurting the performance of the economy. Its complexity 
imposes planning and record keeping costs, facilitates tax shelters, 
and provides potential cover for those who want to cheat. 

Not surprisingly, business tax reform is part of the debate about 
overall tax reform. The debate is occurring at a time when long-range 
projections show that, without a policy change, the gap between 
spending and revenues will widen. 

This testimony reviews the nation’s long term fiscal imbalance and what 
is wrong with the current system of business taxation and provides some 
principles that ought to guide the debate about business tax reform. 

This statement is based on previously published GAO work and reviews of 
relevant literature. 

What GAO Found: 

The size of business tax revenues makes them very relevant to any plan 
for addressing the nation's long-term fiscal imbalance. Reexamining 
both federal spending and revenues, including business tax policy and 
compliance must be part of a multipronged approach to address the 
imbalance. 

Figure: Distribution of Federal Tax Revenue by Type of Tax, Fiscal Year 
2005 ($ billions): 

[See PDF for Image] 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the Office of Management and Budget 
and from Internal Revenue Service (IRS). 

[End of Figure] 

Some features of current business taxes channel investments into tax-
favored activities and away from more productive activities and, 
thereby, reduce the economic well-being of all Americans. Complexity in 
business tax laws imposes costs of its own, facilitates tax shelters, 
and provides potential cover for those who want to cheat. IRS’s latest 
estimates show a business tax gap of at least $141 billion for 2001. 
This in turn undermines confidence in the fairness of our tax 
system—citizens’ confidence that their friends, neighbors, and business 
competitors pay their fair share of taxes. 

Principles that should guide the business tax reform debate include:
* The proposed system should raise sufficient revenue over time to fund 
our current and future expected expenditures.
* The tax base should be as broad as possible, which helps to minimize 
overall tax rates. 
* The proposed system should improve compliance rates by reducing tax 
preferences and complexity and increasing transparency.
* To the extent other goals, such as equity and simplicity, allow, the 
tax system should aim for neutrality by not favoring some business 
activities over others. More neutral tax policy has the potential to 
enhance economic growth, increase productivity and improve the 
competitiveness of the U.S. economy in terms of standard of living.
* The consideration of transition rules must be an integral part of any 
reform proposal. 

[Hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/cgi-bin/getrpt?GAO-06-1113T]. 

To view the full product, including the scope and methodology, click on 
the link above. For more information, contact James White at (202) 512-
9110 or whitej@gao.gov. 

[End of Section] 

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: 

I appreciate this opportunity to contribute to your consideration of 
business tax reform. 

Businesses, both corporate and noncorporate, are a crucial pillar of 
our tax system. Corporate businesses paid $278 billion in federal 
corporate income taxes in fiscal year 2005. In addition, between 
roughly 14 and 19 percent of the income of individuals who pay federal 
income tax comes from business sources.[Footnote 1] Beyond paying 
income taxes, businesses are also responsible for remitting both the 
employer and employee shares of social insurance taxes, which amounted 
to $794 billion in fiscal year 2005. Businesses are vital to our tax 
system in other ways too. They collect and remit a large fraction of 
individual income taxes through withholding. They report information 
about individuals' income and deductible expenses to the Internal 
Revenue Service (IRS). Such withholding and third-party information 
reporting greatly increases individual taxpayers' compliance while 
reducing the size and intrusiveness of IRS. 

Taxes are necessary because they fund a broad array of essential 
services provided by the government. However, business taxes are part 
of our overall fiscal system that, as the committee is aware, is 
currently running large deficits and, as GAO's long-term budget 
simulations illustrate, is projected to run ever larger deficits in the 
future. 

Beyond raising revenue, taxes affect business decision making, thereby 
affecting the performance of the economy. Taxes are only one factor 
affecting business decisions--others include input costs and market 
conditions--but they are a key factor controlled by policymakers. 
Making business decisions based on tax considerations, rather than on 
the underlying economic benefits results in the channeling of some 
investments into less productive activities. This, in turn, reduces the 
standard of living of all Americans. 

Complexity in business tax laws imposes costs of its own, facilitates 
tax shelters, and provides cover for those who want to cheat. Although 
the precise amount of business tax avoidance is unknown, IRS's latest 
estimates show a business tax gap of at least $141 billion for 2001. 
This in turn undermines confidence in the fairness of our tax system-- 
citizens' confidence that their friends, neighbors, and business 
competitors are paying their fair share of taxes. 

Not surprisingly, there is a growing debate about reforming the tax 
system, including business taxes. The debate is partly about whether to 
reform the current income tax so that it has a broader base and lower 
rates or switch in whole or part to some form of a consumption tax. But 
it is also about other fundamental design issues such as whether to 
maintain different tax treatment for corporate and noncorporate 
business and the extent to which business's foreign-source income 
should be taxed. The President's Advisory Panel on Federal Tax Reform 
has taken a major step in beginning this debate. The panel suggested 
two alternative proposals for coordinated reform of the individual and 
corporate income taxes. 

My statement reviews the nation's long-term fiscal imbalance, describes 
what is wrong with our current system of business taxation, lists some 
of the major strategic choices we must make about how to tax businesses 
in the future, and then provides some principles that ought to guide 
the debate about business tax reform. These principles are based on 
three long-standing criteria typically used to evaluate tax policy-- 
equity; economic efficiency; and a combination of simplicity, 
transparency, and administrability--which are discussed later.[Footnote 
2] The principles include the following: 

* The proposed system should raise sufficient revenue over time to fund 
our current and future expected expenditures. 

* The tax base should be as broad as possible, which generally helps to 
minimize tax rates, reduce complexity, lower compliance costs, lower 
economic efficiency costs per dollar of revenue raised, and which may 
improve equity. 

* The proposed system should have attributes associated with high 
compliance rates--namely, taxable transactions that are transparent and 
few tax preferences or complex provisions. 

* To the extent that other objectives, such as equity and simplicity, 
allow, the tax system should aim for increased economic efficiency by 
remaining as neutral as possible in its other structural features; for 
example, avoiding differences in taxation based on legal form of 
organization, source of financing, or type of asset. More neutral tax 
policy has the potential to enhance economic growth, increase 
productivity and improve the competitiveness of the U.S. economy in 
terms of standard of living: 

* Finally, the consideration of transition rules needs to be an 
integral part of the design of a new system. 

My statement today is drawn from previous GAO reports and testimonies 
covering tax reform, alternative tax systems, and the costs of the 
current system, which were done in accordance with generally accepted 
government auditing standards, as well as reviews of relevant 
literature. The discussions in this statement that are not based on our 
own work reflect the consensus (and in some cases competing) views of 
economists as summarized in studies by the Joint Committee on Taxation, 
the Congressional Budget Office, the Congressional Research Service, 
the Department of Treasury, and the President's Advisory Panel on 
Federal Tax Reform. (See app. I for a list of relevant studies by GAO 
and these other sources.) 

Background: 

Current Federal Taxation of Businesses: 

Most income derived from private sector business activity in the United 
States is subject to federal corporate income tax, the individual 
income tax, or both. The tax treatment that applies to a business 
depends on its legal form of organization. Firms that are organized 
under the tax code as "C" corporations (which include most large, 
publicly held corporations) have their profits taxed once at the entity 
level under the corporate income tax (on a form 1120) and then a second 
time under the individual income tax when profits are transferred to 
individual shareholders in the form of dividends or realized capital 
gains. Firms that are organized as "pass-through" entities, such as 
partnerships, limited liability companies, and "S" corporations are 
generally not taxed at the entity level; however, their net incomes are 
passed through each year and taxed in the hands of their partners or 
shareholders under the individual income tax (as part of those 
taxpayers' form 1040 filing).[Footnote 3] Similarly, income from 
businesses that are owned by single individuals enters into the taxable 
incomes of those owners under the individual income tax and is not 
subject to a separate entity-level tax. 

The base of the federal corporate income tax includes net income from 
business operations (receipts, minus the costs of purchased goods, 
labor, interest, and other expenses). It also includes net income that 
corporations earn in the form of interest, dividends, rent, royalties, 
and realized capital gains. The statutory rate of tax on net corporate 
income ranges from 15 to 35 percent, depending on the amount of income 
earned.[Footnote 4] The United States taxes the worldwide income of 
domestic corporations, regardless of where the income is earned, with a 
foreign tax credit for certain taxes paid to other countries. However, 
the timing of the tax liability depends on several factors, including 
whether the income is from a U.S. or foreign source and, if it is from 
a foreign source, whether it is earned through direct operations or 
through a subsidiary. 

The base of the individual income tax covers business-source income 
paid to individuals, such as dividends, realized net capital gains on 
corporate equity, and income from self-employment. The statutory rates 
of tax on net taxable income range from 10 percent to 35 percent. Lower 
rates (generally 5 percent and 15 percent, depending on taxable income) 
apply to long-term capital gains and dividend income.[Footnote 5] Sole 
proprietors also pay both the employer and employee shares of social 
insurance taxes on their net business income. Generally, a U.S. citizen 
or resident pays tax on his or her worldwide income, including income 
derived from foreign-source dividends and capital gains subject to a 
credit for foreign taxes paid on such income. 

Criteria for Evaluating Business Tax Systems: 

Three long-standing criteria--economic efficiency, equity, and a 
combination of simplicity, transparency and administrability--are 
typically used to evaluate tax policy. These criteria are often in 
conflict with each other, and as a result, there are usually trade-offs 
to consider and people are likely to disagree about the relative 
importance of the criteria. 

Specific aspects of business taxes can be evaluated in terms of how 
they support or detract from the efficiency, equity, simplicity, 
transparency, and administrability of the overall tax system. To the 
extent that a tax system is not simple and efficient, it imposes costs 
on taxpayers beyond the payments they make to the U.S. Treasury. As 
shown in figure 1, the total cost of any tax from a taxpayer's point of 
view is the sum of the tax liability, the cost of complying with the 
tax system, and the economic efficiency costs that the tax imposes. In 
deciding on the size of government, we balance the total cost of taxes 
with the benefits provided by government programs. 

Figure 1: Components of the Total Cost of a Tax to Taxpayers: 

[See PDF for image] 

Source: GAO. 

[End of figure] 

A complete evaluation of the tax treatment of businesses, which is a 
critical element of our overall federal tax system, cannot be made 
without considering how business taxation interacts with and 
complements the other elements of the overall system, such as the tax 
treatment of individuals and excise taxes on selected goods and 
services. This integrated approach is also appropriate for evaluating 
reform alternatives, regardless of whether those alternatives take the 
form of a simplified income tax system, a consumption tax system, or 
some combination of the two. 

Taxes on Business Income Are a Significant Source of Federal Revenue 
and Must Be Part of the Overall Considerations for Fiscal Reform: 

Businesses contribute significant revenues to the federal government, 
both directly and indirectly. As figure 2 shows, corporate businesses 
paid $278 billion in corporate income tax directly to the federal 
government in 2005. Individuals earn income from business investment in 
the form of dividends and realized capital gains from C corporations; 
income allocations from partnerships and S corporations; 
entrepreneurial income from their own sole proprietorships; and rents 
and royalties. In recent years this business-source income, which is 
all taxed under the individual income tax, has amounted to between 
roughly 14 percent and 19 percent of the income of individuals who have 
paid individual income tax.[Footnote 6] In addition to the taxes that 
are paid on business-source income, most of the remainder of federal 
taxes is collected and passed on to the government by businesses. 

Figure 2: Distribution of Federal Tax Revenue by Type of Tax, 2005 
(Billions of Dollars): 

[See PDF for image] 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the Office of Management and Budget 
and from the Internal revenue service (IRS). 

Note: The business source income referred to in the figure includes the 
income of sole proprietors, income from partnerships and S 
corporations, dividends, capital gains, rents, and royalties. The 
percentage equals the ratio of (net business-source income minus 
losses) over adjusted gross income. When computing these percentages we 
did not include any income or losses of individuals who did not have a 
tax liability in a given year. 

[End of figure] 

Business tax revenues of the magnitude discussed make them very 
relevant to considerations about how to address the nation's long-term 
fiscal imbalance. Over the long term, the United States faces a large 
and growing structural budget deficit primarily caused by demographic 
trends and rising health care costs as shown in figure 3, and 
exacerbated over time by growing interest on the ever-larger federal 
debt. [Footnote 7] Continuing on this imprudent and unsustainable 
fiscal path will gradually erode, if not suddenly damage, our economy, 
our standard of living, and ultimately our national security. 

Figure 3: Composition of Federal Spending as a Share of Gross Domestic 
Product (GDP), Assuming Discretionary Spending Grows with GDP after 
2006 and All Expiring Tax Provisions Are Extended: 

[See PDF for image] 

Source: GAO's August 2006 analysis. 

Note: The revenue projection in this figure includes certain tax 
provisions that expired at the end of 2005. 

[End of figure] 

We cannot grow our way out of this long-term fiscal challenge because 
the imbalance between spending and revenue is so large. We will need to 
make tough choices using a multipronged approach: (1) revise budget 
processes and financial reporting requirements; (2) restructure 
entitlement programs; (3) reexamine the base of discretionary spending 
and other spending; and (4) review and revise tax policy, including tax 
expenditures, and tax enforcement programs. Business tax policy, 
business tax expenditures, and business tax enforcement need to be part 
of the overall tax review because of the amount of revenue at stake. 

Business tax expenditures reduce the revenue that would otherwise be 
raised from businesses. As already noted, to reduce their tax 
liabilities, businesses can take advantage of preferential provisions 
in the tax code, such as exclusions, exemptions, deductions, credits, 
preferential rates, and deferral of tax liability. Tax preferences-- 
which are legally known as tax expenditures--are often aimed at policy 
goals similar to those of federal spending programs. For example, there 
are different tax expenditures intended to encourage economic 
development in disadvantaged areas and stimulate research and 
development, while there are also federal spending programs that have 
similar purposes. Also, by narrowing the tax base, business tax 
expenditures have the effect of raising either business tax rates or 
the rates on other taxpayers in order to generate a given amount of 
revenue. 

Efficiency, Complexity, Compliance, and Equity Concerns Contribute to 
Calls for Business Tax Reform: 

The design of the current system of business taxation causes economic 
inefficiency and is complex. The complexity provides fertile ground for 
noncompliance and raises equity concerns. 

Varying Effective Rates of Taxation Across Different Types of Business 
Investments Reduce Economic Efficiency: 

Our current system for taxing business income causes economic 
inefficiency because it imposes significantly different effective rates 
of tax on different types of investments.[Footnote 8] Tax treatment 
that is not neutral across different types of capital investment causes 
significant economic inefficiency by guiding investments to lightly 
taxed activities rather than those with high pretax productivity. 

However, the goal of tax policy is not to eliminate efficiency costs. 
The goal is to design a tax system that produces a desired amount of 
revenue and balances economic efficiency with other objectives, such as 
equity, simplicity, transparency, and administrability. Every practical 
tax system imposes efficiency costs. 

There are some features of current business taxation that have 
attracted criticism by economists and other tax experts because of 
efficiency costs. My point in raising them here is not that these 
features need to be changed--that is a policy judgment for Congress to 
make as it balances various goals. Rather, my point is that these 
economic consequences of tax policy need to be considered as we think 
about reform. The following are among the most noted cases of 
nonneutral taxation in the federal business tax system: 

* Income earned on equity-financed investments made by C corporations 
is taxed twice--under both the corporate and individual income taxes, 
whereas no other business income is taxed more than once. Moreover, 
even noncorporate business investment is taxed more heavily than owner- 
occupied housing--a form of capital investment that receives very 
preferential treatment. As a result, resources have been shifted away 
from higher-return business investment into owner-occupied housing, 
and, within the business sector, resources have been shifted from 
higher-return corporations to noncorporate businesses. Such shifting of 
investment makes workers less productive than they would be under a 
more neutral tax system. This results in employees receiving lower 
wages because increases in employee wages are generally tied to 
increases in productivity. [Footnote 9] As noted above, such efficiency 
costs may be worth paying in order to meet other policy goals. For 
example, many policymakers advocate increased homeownership as a social 
policy goal. 

* Depreciation allowances under the tax code vary considerably in 
generosity across different assets causing effective tax rates to vary 
and, thereby, favoring investment in certain assets over others. For 
example, researchers have found that the returns on most types of 
investments in equipment are taxed more favorably than are most 
investments in nonresidential buildings.[Footnote 10] These biases 
shift resources away from some investments in buildings that would have 
been more productive than some of the equipment investments that are 
being made instead. 

* Tax rules for corporations favor the use of debt over shareholder 
equity as a source of finance for investment. The return on debt- 
financed investment consists of interest payments to the corporation's 
creditors, which are deductible by the corporations. Consequently, that 
return is taxed only once--in the hands of the creditors. In contrast, 
the return on equity-financed investment consists of dividends and 
capital gains, which are not deductible by the corporation. These forms 
of income that are taxed under the individual tax are paid out of 
income that has already been subject to the corporate income tax. The 
bias against equity finance induces corporations to have less of an 
"equity cushion" against business downturns.[Footnote 11] 

* Capital gains on corporate equity are taxed more favorably than 
dividends because that tax can be deferred until the gains are realized 
(typically when shareholders sell their stock). This bias against 
dividend payments likely means that more profits are retained within 
corporations than otherwise would be the case and, therefore, the flow 
of capital to its most productive uses is being constrained.[Footnote 
12] 

* The complex set of rules governing U.S. taxation of the worldwide 
income of domestic corporations (those incorporated in the United 
States) leads to wide variations in the effective rate of tax paid on 
that income, based on the nature and location of each corporation's 
foreign operations and the effort put into tax planning. In effect, the 
active foreign income of some U.S. corporations is taxed more heavily 
than if the United States followed the practice of many other countries 
and exempted such income from tax. However, other U.S. corporations are 
able to take advantage of flexibilities in the U.S. tax rules in order 
to achieve treatment that is equivalent to or, in some cases, more 
favorable than the so-called "territorial" tax systems that exempt 
foreign-source active business income. As a consequence, some U.S. 
corporations face a tax disadvantage, while others have an advantage, 
relative to foreign corporations when competing in foreign countries. 
Those U.S. corporations that have a disadvantage are likely to locate a 
smaller share of their investment overseas than would be the case in a 
tax-free world; the opposite is true for those U.S. corporations with 
the tax advantage. Moreover, the tax system encourages U.S. 
corporations to alter their cash-management and financing decisions 
(such as by delaying the repatriation of profits) in order to reduce 
their taxes. 

The taxation of business income is part of the broader taxation of 
income from capital. The taxation of capital income in general (even 
when that taxation is uniformly applied) causes another form of 
inefficiency beyond the inefficiencies caused by the aforementioned 
cases of differential taxation across types of investments. This 
additional inefficiency occurs because taxes on capital reduce the 
after-tax return on savings and, thereby, distort the choice that 
individuals make between current consumption and saving for future 
consumption. However, although research shows that the demand for some 
types of savings, such as the demand for tax exempt bonds, is 
responsive to tax changes, there is greater uncertainty about the 
effects of tax changes on other choices, such as aggregate savings. 

Sometimes the concerns about the negative effects of taxation on the 
U.S. economy are couched in terms of "competitiveness," where the 
vaguely defined term competitiveness is often defined as the ability of 
U.S. businesses to export their products to foreign markets and to 
compete against foreign imports into the U.S. market. The goal of those 
who push for this type of competitiveness is to improve the U.S. 
balance of trade. However, economists generally agree that trying to 
increase the U.S. balance of trade through targeted tax breaks for 
exports does not work. Such a policy, aimed at lowering the prices of 
exports, would be offset by an increase in the value of the dollar 
which would make U.S. exports more expensive and imports into the 
Unites States less expensive, ultimately leaving both the balance of 
trade and the standard of living of Americans unchanged.[Footnote 13] 

An alternative definition of competitiveness that is also sometimes 
used in tax policy debates refers to the ability of U.S.-owned firms 
operating abroad to compete in foreign markets. The current U.S. policy 
of taxing the worldwide income of U.S. businesses places some of their 
foreign operations at a disadvantage. The tradeoffs between a worldwide 
system and a territorial tax system are discussed below. 

Businesses Bear Significant Compliance Burdens Arising Both from the 
Complexity of the Tax System and from Their Multiple Roles within the 
System: 

Tax compliance requirements for businesses are extensive and complex. 
Rules governing the computation of taxable income, expense deductions, 
and tax credits of U.S. corporations that do business in multiple 
foreign countries are particularly complex. But even small businesses 
face multiple levels of tax requirements of varying difficulty. In 
addition to computing and documenting their income, expenses, and 
qualifications for various tax credits, businesses with employees are 
responsible for collecting and remitting (at varying intervals) several 
federal taxes on the incomes of those employees. Moreover, if the 
businesses choose to offer their employees retirement plans and other 
fringe benefits, they can substantially increase the number of filings 
they must make. Businesses also have information-reporting 
responsibilities--employers send wage statements to their employees and 
to IRS; banks and other financial intermediaries send investment income 
statements to clients and to IRS.[Footnote 14] Finally, a relatively 
small percentage of all businesses (which nevertheless number in the 
hundreds of thousands) are required to participate in the collection of 
various federal excise taxes levied on fuels, heavy trucks and 
trailers, communications, guns, tobacco, and alcohol, among other 
products. 

It is difficult for researchers to accurately estimate compliance costs 
for the tax system as a whole or for particular types of taxpayers 
because taxpayers generally do not keep records of the time and money 
spent complying with tax requirements. Studies we found that focus on 
the compliance costs of businesses estimate them to be between about 
$40 billion and $85 billion per year.[Footnote 15] None of these 
estimates include the costs to businesses of collecting and remitting 
income and payroll taxes for their employees. The accuracy of these 
business compliance cost estimates is uncertain due to the low rates of 
response to their data-collection surveys. In addition, the range in 
estimates across the studies is due, among other things, to differences 
in monetary values used (ranging between $25 per hour and $37.26 per 
hour), differences in the business populations covered, and differences 
in the tax years covered. 

Business Tax Complexity Also Makes IRS's Job of Enforcing Tax Rules 
Very Challenging and Can Reduce Public Confidence in the Fairness of 
the System: 

Although the precise amount of business tax avoidance is unknown, IRS's 
latest estimates of tax compliance show a tax gap of at least $141 
billion for tax year 2001 between the business taxes that individual 
and corporate taxpayers paid and what they should have paid under the 
law.[Footnote 16] Corporations contributed about $32 billion to the tax 
gap by underreporting about $30 billion in taxes on tax returns and 
failing to pay about $2 billion in taxes that were reported on returns. 
Individual taxpayers that underreported their business income accounted 
for the remaining $109 billion of the business income tax gap.[Footnote 
17] 

A complex tax code, complicated business transactions, and often 
multinational corporate structures make determining business tax 
liabilities and the extent of corporate tax avoidance a challenge. Tax 
avoidance has become such a concern that some tax experts say corporate 
tax departments have become "profit centers" as corporations seek to 
take advantage of the tax laws in order to maximize shareholder value. 
Some corporate tax avoidance is clearly legal, some falls in gray areas 
of the tax code, and some is clearly noncompliance or illegal, as shown 
by IRS's tax gap estimate. 

Often business tax avoidance is legal. For example, multinational 
corporations can locate active trade or business operations in 
jurisdictions that have lower effective tax rates than does the United 
States and, unless and until they repatriate the income, defer taxation 
in the United States on that income, thus reducing their effective tax 
rate. In addition, investors can avoid paying the corporate income tax 
by putting their money into unincorporated businesses or into real 
estate. 

Complicating corporate tax compliance is the fact that in many cases 
the law is unclear or subject to differing interpretations. In fact, 
some have postulated that major corporations' tax returns are actually 
just the opening bid in an extended negotiation with IRS to determine a 
corporation's tax liability. An illustration--once again from the 
complex area of international tax rules--is transfer pricing. Transfer 
pricing involves setting the appropriate price for such things as 
goods, services, or intangible property (such as patents, trademarks, 
copyrights, technology, or "know-how") that is transferred between the 
U.S.-based operations of a multinational company and a foreign 
affiliate. If the price paid by the affiliate to the U.S. operation is 
understated, the profits of the U.S. operation are reduced and U.S. 
taxable income is inappropriately reduced or eliminated. The standard 
for judging the correct price is the price that would have been paid 
between independent enterprises acting at "arm's length." However, it 
can be extremely difficult to establish what an arm's length price 
would be. Given the global economy and the number of multinational 
firms with some U.S.-based operations, opportunities for transfer 
pricing disputes are likely to grow. 

Tax shelters are one example of how tax avoidance, including corporate 
tax avoidance, can shade into the illegal. Some tax shelters are legal 
though perhaps aggressive interpretations of the law, but others cross 
the line.[Footnote 18] Abusive shelters often are complex transactions 
that manipulate many parts of the tax code or regulations and are 
typically buried among legitimate transactions reported on tax returns. 
Because these transactions are often composed of many pieces located in 
several parts of a complex tax return, they are essentially hidden from 
plain sight, which contributes to the difficulty of determining the 
scope of the abusive shelter problem. Often lacking economic substance 
or a business purpose other than generating tax benefits, abusive 
shelters have been promoted by some tax professionals, often in 
confidence, for significant fees, sometimes with the participation of 
tax-indifferent parties, such as foreign or tax-exempt entities. These 
shelters may involve unnecessary steps and flow-through entities, such 
as partnerships, which make detection of these transactions more 
difficult. 

Regarding compliance with our tax laws, the success of our tax system 
hinges greatly on individual and business taxpayers' perception of its 
fairness and understandability. Compliance is influenced not only by 
the effectiveness of IRS's enforcement efforts but also by Americans' 
attitudes about the tax system and their government. A recent survey 
indicated that about 10 percent of respondents say it is acceptable to 
cheat on their taxes. Furthermore, the complexity of, and frequent 
revisions to, the tax system make it more difficult and costly for 
taxpayers who want to comply to do so and for IRS to explain and 
enforce tax laws. The lack of transparency also fuels disrespect for 
the tax system and the government. Thus, a crucial challenge in 
evaluating our business tax system will be to determine how we can best 
strengthen enforcement of existing laws to give businesses owners 
confidence that their competitors are paying their fair share and to 
give wage earners confidence that businesses in general bear their 
share of taxes. One option that has been suggested as a means of 
improving public confidence in the tax system's fairness is to make the 
reconciliation between book and tax income that businesses present on 
schedule M-3 of their tax returns available for public review. 

Business Tax Reform Entails Broad Design Choices about the Overall Tax 
System: 

Reform of our business tax system will necessarily mean making broad 
design choices about the overall tax system and how business taxes are 
coordinated with other taxes. The tax reform debate of the last several 
years has focused attention on several important choices, including the 
extent to which our system should be closer to the extreme of a pure 
income tax or the other extreme of a pure consumption tax, the extent 
to which sales by U.S. businesses outside of this country should be 
taxed, the extent to which taxes should be collected from businesses or 
individuals, and the extent to which taxpayers are compensated for 
losses or costs they incur during the transition to any new tax system. 
Generally there is no single "right" decision about these choices and 
the options are not limited to selecting a system that is at one 
extreme or the other along the continuum of potential systems. The 
choices will involve making tradeoffs between the various goals for our 
tax system. 

Income vs. Consumption as the Tax Base: 

The fundamental difference between income and consumption taxes lies in 
their treatment of savings and investment. Income can be used for 
either consumption or saving and investment. The tax base of a pure 
income tax includes all income, regardless of what it is ultimately 
used for; in contrast, the tax base of a consumption tax excludes 
income devoted to saving and investment (until it is ultimately used 
for consumption). The current tax system is a hybrid between a pure 
income tax and a pure consumption tax because it effectively exempts 
some types of savings and investment but taxes other types. 

As noted earlier, evidence is inconclusive regarding whether a shift 
closer to a consumption tax base would significantly affect the level 
of savings by U.S. taxpayers. There is, however, a consensus among 
economists that uneven tax treatment across different types of 
investment should be avoided unless the efficiency costs resulting from 
preferential tax treatment are outweighed by the social benefits 
generated by the tax preference. That objective could be achieved under 
either a consumption tax that exempts all new savings and investment 
from taxation (which means that all business profits are exempt) or a 
revised income tax that taxed all investments at the same effective 
rate. In comparison to the current system, a consumption tax's 
exemption of business-source income would likely encourage U.S. 
businesses to increase their investment in the United States relative 
to their foreign investment. 

Both income and consumption taxes can be structured in a variety of 
ways, as discussed in the following subsections, and the choice of a 
specific design for either type of tax can have as significant 
implications for efficiency, administrability, and equity as the choice 
between a consumption or income base. [Footnote 19] The exemption of 
saving and investment can be accomplished in different ways, so 
consumption taxes can be structured differently and yet still have the 
same overall tax base. 

Collecting the Tax at the Business or Individual Level: 

Both income and consumption taxes can be levied on individuals or 
businesses, or on a combination of the two. Whether collected from 
individuals or businesses, ultimately, individuals will bear the 
economic burden of any tax (as wage earners, shareholders, or 
consumers). The choice of whether to collect a tax at the business 
level or the individual level depends on whether it is thought to be 
desirable to levy different taxes on different individuals. A business- 
level tax, whether levied on income or consumption, can be collected 
"at source"--that is, where it is generated--so there can be many fewer 
tax filers and returns to administer. Business-level taxes cannot, 
however, directly tax different individuals at different rates. 
Individual-level taxes can allow for distinctions between different 
individuals; for example, standard deductions or graduated rates can be 
used to tax individuals with low income (or consumption) at a lower 
rate than individuals with greater income (or consumption). However, 
individual-level taxes require more tax returns, impose higher 
compliance costs, and would generally require a larger tax 
administration system.[Footnote 20] 

A national retail sales tax, a consumption value-added tax, and an 
income value-added tax are examples of taxes that would be collected 
only at the business level. A personal consumption tax and an 
integrated individual income tax are examples of taxes that would be 
collected only at the individual level. The "flat tax" proposed by 
economists Robert Hall and Alvin Rabushka that has received attention 
in recent years is an example of a tax collected at both the business 
and individual level.[Footnote 21] Our current system for taxing 
corporate-source income involves taxation at both the corporate and 
individual level in a manner that results in the double taxation of the 
same income. 

Territorial vs. Worldwide Taxation under an Income Tax: 

Under a pure worldwide tax system the United States would tax the 
income of U.S. corporations, as it is earned, regardless of where it is 
earned, and at the same time provide a foreign tax credit that ensures 
that the combined rate of tax that a corporation pays to all 
governments on each dollar of income is exactly equal to the U.S. 
corporate tax rate. Some basic differences between the current U.S. tax 
system and a pure worldwide system are that (1) in many cases the U.S. 
system permits corporations to defer U.S. tax on their foreign-source 
income until it is repatriated and (2) the U.S. foreign tax credit is 
limited to the amount of U.S. tax that would be due on a corporation's 
foreign-source income. In cases where the rate of foreign tax on a 
corporation's income exceeds the U.S. tax rate, the corporation is left 
paying the higher rate of tax. 

Under a pure territorial tax system the United States would simply 
exempt all foreign-source income. (No major country has a pure 
territorial system; they all tax mobile forms of foreign-source income, 
such as royalties and income from securities.) The current U.S. tax 
system has some features that result in some cases in treatment similar 
to what would exist under a territorial system. First, corporations can 
defer U.S. tax indefinitely on certain foreign-source income, as long 
as they keep it reinvested abroad. Second, in certain cases U.S. 
corporations are able to use the excess credits that they earned for 
taxes they paid to high-tax countries to completely offset any U.S. tax 
that they would normally have to pay on income they earned in low-tax 
countries.[Footnote 22] As a result, that income from low-tax countries 
remains untaxed by the United States--just as it would be under a 
territorial system. In fact, there are some cases where U.S. 
corporations enjoy tax treatment that is more favorable than under a 
territorial system. This occurs when they pay no U.S. tax on foreign- 
source income yet are still able to deduct expenses allocable to that 
income. For example, a U.S. parent corporation can borrow money and 
invest it in a foreign subsidiary. The parent corporation generally can 
deduct its interest payments from its U.S. taxes even if it defers U.S. 
tax on the subsidiary's income by leaving it overseas. 

Proponents of a worldwide tax system and proponents of a territorial 
system both argue that their preferred systems would provide important 
forms of tax neutrality. Under a pure worldwide system all of the 
income that a U.S. corporation earns abroad would be taxed at the same 
effective rate that a corporation earning the same amount of income 
domestically would pay. Such a tax system is neutral in the sense that 
it does not influence the decision of U.S. corporations to invest 
abroad or at home. If the U.S. had a pure territorial tax system all of 
the income that U.S. corporations earn in a particular country would be 
taxed at the same rate as corporations that are residents of that 
country. The pure territorial system is neutral in the specific sense 
that U.S. corporations investing in a foreign country would not be at a 
disadvantage relative to corporations residing in that country or 
relative to other foreign corporations investing there.[Footnote 23] In 
a world where each country sets its own tax rules it is impossible to 
achieve both types of neutrality at the same time, so tradeoffs are 
unavoidable. 

A change from the current tax system to a pure territorial one is 
likely to have mixed effects on tax compliance and administration. On 
the one hand, a pure worldwide tax system, or even the current system, 
may preserve the U.S. tax base better than a territorial system would 
because U.S. taxpayers would have greater incentive under a territorial 
system to shift income and investment into low-tax jurisdictions via 
transfer pricing. On the other hand, a pure territorial system may be 
less complex for IRS to administer and for taxpayers to comply with 
than the current tax system because there would be no need for the 
antideferral rules or the foreign tax credit, which are among the most 
complex features of the current system. 

Destination-Principle vs. Origin-Principle Consumption Tax: 

Broad-based consumption taxes can differ depending on whether they are 
imposed under a destination principle, which holds that goods and 
services should be taxed in the countries where they are consumed, or 
an origin principle, which holds that goods and services should be 
taxed in the countries where they are produced. In the long run, after 
markets have adjusted, neither type of tax would have a significant 
effect on the U.S. trade balance. This is true for a destination-based 
tax because products consumed in the United States would be taxed at 
the same rate, regardless of where they were produced. Therefore, such 
a tax would not influence a consumer's choice between buying a car 
produced in the United States or one imported from Japan. And at the 
same time, U.S. exports of cars would not be affected by the tax 
because they would be exempted. An origin-based consumption tax would 
not affect the trade balance because the tax effects that taxes have on 
prices would ultimately be countered by the same price adjustment 
mechanism that we discussed earlier with respect to targeted tax 
subsidies for exports.[Footnote 24] 

A national retail sales tax limited to final consumption goods would be 
a destination-principle tax; it would tax imports when sold at retail 
in this country and would not tax exports. Value-added taxes can be 
designed as either destination or origin-principle taxes. 

A personal consumption tax, collected at the individual level, would 
apply to U.S. residents or citizens and could be formulated to tax 
their consumption regardless of whether it is done domestically or 
overseas. Under such a system, income earned abroad would be taxable 
but funds saved or invested abroad would be deductible. In that case, 
foreign-produced goods imported into the United States or consumed by 
U.S. citizens abroad would be taxed. U.S. exports would only be taxed 
to the extent that they are consumed by U.S. citizens abroad. 

The Extent of Transition Provisions: 

A wide range of options exist for moving from the current business tax 
system to an alternative one, and the way that any transition is 
formulated could have significant effects for economic efficiency, 
equity, taxpayer compliance burden, and tax administration. For 
example, one transition issue involves whether tax credits and other 
tax benefits already earned under the current tax would be made 
available under a new system. Businesses that are deducting 
depreciation under the current system would not have the opportunity to 
continue depreciating their capital goods under a VAT unless special 
rules were included to permit it. Similar problems could arise with 
businesses' carrying forward net operating losses and recovering 
unclaimed tax credits. Depending on how these and other issues are 
addressed, taxpayer compliance burden and tax administration 
responsibilities could be greater during the transition period than 
they currently are or than they would be once the transition ends. 
Transition rules could also substantially reduce the new system's tax 
base, thereby requiring higher tax rates during the transition if 
revenue neutrality were to be achieved.[Footnote 25] 

Criteria for a Good Tax System Provide Principles to Guide Decisions 
and Issues for Consideration: 

Our publication, Understanding the Tax Reform Debate: Background, 
Criteria, and Questions,[Footnote 26] may be useful in guiding 
policymakers as they consider tax reform proposals. It was designed to 
aid policymakers in thinking about how to develop tax policy for the 
21st century. The criteria for a good tax system, which our report 
discusses, provide the basis for a set of principles that should guide 
Congress as it considers the choices and tradeoffs involved in tax 
system reform. And, as I also noted earlier, proposals for reforming 
business taxation cannot be evaluated without considering how that 
business taxation will interact with and complement the other elements 
of our overall future tax system. 

The proposed system should raise sufficient revenue over time to fund 
our expected expenditures. As I mentioned earlier, we will fall 
woefully short of achieving this end if current spending or revenue 
trends are not altered. Although we clearly must restructure major 
entitlement programs and the basis of other federal spending, it is 
unlikely that our long-term fiscal challenge will be resolved solely by 
cutting spending. 

The proposal should look to future needs. Like many spending programs, 
the current tax system was developed in a profoundly different time. We 
live now in a much more global economy, with highly mobile capital, and 
with investment options available to ordinary citizens that were not 
even imagined decades ago. We have growing concentrations of income and 
wealth. More firms operate multinationally and willingly move 
operations and capital around the world as they see best for their 
firms. 

As an adjunct to looking forward when making reforms, better 
information on existing commitments and promises must be coupled with 
estimates of the long-term discounted net present value costs from 
spending and tax commitments comprising longer-term exposures for the 
federal budget beyond the existing 10-year budget projection window. 

The tax base should be as broad as possible. Broad-based tax systems 
with minimal exceptions have many advantages. Fewer exceptions 
generally means less complexity, less compliance cost, less economic 
efficiency loss, and by increasing transparency may improve equity or 
perceptions of equity. This suggests that eliminating or consolidating 
numerous tax expenditures must be considered. In many cases tax 
preferences are simply a form of "back-door spending." We need to be 
sure that the benefits achieved from having these special provisions 
are worth the associated revenue losses just as we must ensure that 
outlay programs--which may be attempting to achieve the same purposes 
as tax expenditures--achieve outcomes commensurate with their costs. 
And it is important to supplement these cost-benefit evaluations with 
analyses of distributional effects--i.e., who bears the costs of the 
preferences and who receives the benefits. To the extent tax 
expenditures are retained, consideration should be given to whether 
they could be better targeted to meet an identified need. 

If we must raise revenues, doing so from a broad base and a lower rate 
will help minimize economic efficiency costs. Broad-based tax systems 
can yield the same revenue as more narrowly based systems at lower tax 
rates. The combination of less direct intervention in the marketplace 
from special tax preferences, and the lower rates possible from broad- 
based systems, can have substantial benefits for economic efficiency. 
For instance, one commonly cited rule of thumb regarding economic 
efficiency costs of tax increases is that they rise proportionately 
faster than the tax rates. In other words, a 10 percent tax increase 
could raise the economic efficiency costs of a tax system by much more 
than 10 percent. 

Aside from the base-broadening that minimizes targeted tax preferences 
favoring specific types of investment or other business behavior, it is 
also desirable on the grounds of economic efficiency to extend the 
principle of tax neutrality to the broader structural features of a 
business tax system. For example, improvements in economic efficiency 
can also be gained by avoiding differences in tax treatment, such as 
the differences in the current system based on legal form of 
organization, source of financing, and the nature and location of 
foreign operations. Removing such differences can shift resources to 
more productive uses, increasing economic performance and the standard 
of living of Americans. Shifting resources to more productive uses can 
result in a step up in the level of economic activity which would be 
measured as a one-time increase in the rate of growth. Tax changes that 
increase efficiency can also increase the long-term rate of economic 
growth if they increase the rate of technological change; however, not 
all efficiency-increasing tax changes will do so.[Footnote 27] 

Impact on the standard of living of Americans is also a useful 
criterion for evaluating policies to improve U.S. competitiveness. As 
was discussed earlier, narrower goals and policies, such as increasing 
the U.S. balance of trade through targeted tax breaks aimed at 
encouraging exports, are generally viewed as ineffective by economists. 
What determines the standard of living of Americans and how it compares 
to the standard of living in other countries is the productivity of 
American workers and capital. That productivity is determined by 
factors such as education, technological innovation, and the amount of 
investment in the U.S. economy. Tax policy can contribute to American 
productivity in several ways. One, discussed in this statement, is 
through neutral taxation of investment alternatives. Another, which I 
have discussed on many occasions, is through fiscal policy. Borrowing 
to finance persistent federal deficits absorbs savings from the private 
sector reducing funds available for investment. Higher saving and 
investment from a more balanced fiscal policy would contribute to 
increased productivity and a higher standard of living for Americans 
over the long term. 

A reformed business tax system should have attributes associated with 
high compliance rates. Because any tax system can be subject to tax 
gaps, the administrability of reformed systems should be considered as 
part of the debate for change. In general, a reformed system is most 
likely to have a small tax gap if the system has few tax preferences or 
complex provisions and taxable transactions are transparent. 
Transparency in the context of tax administration is best achieved when 
third parties report information both to the taxpayer and the tax 
administrator. 

Minimizing tax code complexity has the potential to reduce 
noncompliance for at least three broad reasons. First, it could help 
taxpayers to comply voluntarily with more certainty, reducing 
inadvertent errors by those who want to comply but are confused because 
of complexity. Second, it may limit opportunities for tax evasion, 
reducing intentional noncompliance by taxpayers who can misuse the 
complex code provisions to hide their noncompliance or to achieve ends 
through tax shelters. Third, reducing tax-code complexity could improve 
taxpayers' willingness to comply voluntarily. 

Finally, the consideration of transition rules needs to be an integral 
part of the design of a new system. The effects of these rules can be 
too significant to leave them simply as an afterthought in the reform 
process. 

Concluding Observations: 

The problems that I have reviewed today relating to the compliance 
costs, efficiency costs, equity, and tax gap associated with the 
current business tax system would seem to make a strong case for a 
comprehensive review and reform of our tax policy. Further, businesses 
operate in a world that is profoundly different--more competitive and 
more global--than when many of the existing provisions of the tax code 
were adopted. Despite numerous and repeated calls for reform, progress 
has been slow. I discussed reasons for the slow progress in a previous 
hearing on individual tax reform before this committee. One reason why 
reform is difficult to accomplish is that the provisions of the tax 
code that generate compliance costs, efficiency costs, the tax gap and 
inequities also benefit many taxpayers. Reform is also difficult 
because, even when there is agreement on the amount of revenue to 
raise, there are differing opinions on the appropriate balance among 
the often conflicting objectives of equity, efficiency, and 
administrability. This, in turn, leads to widely divergent views on 
even the basic direction of reform. 

However, I have described some basic principles that ought to guide 
business tax reform. One of them is revenue sufficiency. Fiscal 
necessity, prompted by the nation's unsustainable fiscal path, will 
eventually force changes to our spending and tax policies. We must 
fundamentally rethink policies and everything must be on the table. 
Tough choices will have to be made about the appropriate degree of 
emphasis on cutting back federal programs versus increasing tax 
revenue. 

Other principles, such as broadening the tax base and otherwise 
promoting tax neutrality, could help improve economic performance. 
While economic growth alone will not solve our long-term fiscal 
problems, an improvement in our overall economic performance makes 
dealing with those problems easier. 

The recent report of the President's Advisory Panel on Federal Tax 
Reform recommended two different tax reform plans. Although each plan 
is intended to improve economic efficiency and simplify the tax system, 
neither of them addresses the growing imbalance between federal 
spending and revenues that I have highlighted. One approach for getting 
the process of comprehensive fiscal reform started would be through the 
establishment of a credible, capable, and bipartisan commission, to 
examine options for a combination of selected entitlement and tax 
reform issues. 

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee, this concludes my statement. 
I would be pleased to answer any questions you may have at this time. 

Contact and Acknowledgments: 

For further information on this testimony, please contact James White 
on (202) 512-9110 or whitej@gao.gov. Contact points for our Offices of 
Congressional Relations and Public Affairs may be found on the last 
page of this testimony. Individuals making key contributions to this 
testimony include Jim Wozny, Assistant Director; Donald Marples; Jeff 
Arkin; and Cheryl Peterson. 

[End of section] 

Appendix I: List of Studies Reviewed: 

Government Accountability Office: 

Individual Income Tax Policy: Streamlining, Simplification, and 
Additional Reforms Are Desirable. GAO-06-1028T. Washington, D.C.: 
August 3, 2006. 

Tax Compliance: Opportunities Exist to Reduce the Tax Gap Using a 
Variety of Approaches. GAO-06-1000T. Washington, D.C.: July 26, 2006. 

Tax Compliance: Challenges to Corporate Tax Enforcement and Options to 
Improve Securities Basis Reporting. GAO-06-851T. Washington, D.C.: June 
13, 2006. 

Understanding the Tax Reform Debate: Background, Criteria, & Questions. 
GAO-05-1009SP. Washington, D.C.: September 2005. 

Government Performance and Accountability: Tax Expenditures Represent a 
Substantial Federal Commitment and Need to Be Reexamined. GAO-05-690. 
Washington, D.C.: Sept. 23, 2005. 

Tax Policy: Summary of Estimates of the Costs of the Federal Tax 
System. GAO-05-878. Washington, D.C.: August 26, 2005. 

Tax Compliance: Reducing the Tax Gap Can Contribute to Fiscal 
Sustainability but Will Require a Variety of Strategies. GAO-05-527T. 
Washington, D.C.: April 14, 2005. 

21st Century Challenges: Reexamining the Base of the Federal 
Government. GAO-05-325SP. Washington, D.C.: February 1, 2005. 

Tax Administration: Potential Impact of Alternative Taxes on Taxpayers 
and Administrators. GAO/GGD-98-37. Washington, D.C.: January 14, 1998. 

Congressional Budget Office: 

Corporate Income Tax Rates: International Comparisons. Washington, 
D.C.: November 2005. 

Taxing Capital Income: Effective Rates and Approaches to Reform. 
Washington, D.C.: October 2005. 

Effects of Adopting a Value-Added Tax. Washington, D.C.: February 1992. 

Congressional Research Service: 

Brumbaugh, David L. Taxes and International Competitiveness. RS22445. 
Washington, D.C.: May 19, 2006. 

Brumbaugh, David L. Federal Business Taxation: The Current System, Its 
Effects, and Options for Reform. RL33171. Washington, D.C.: December 
20, 2005. 

Gravelle, Jane G. Capital Income Tax Revisions and Effective Tax Rates. 
RL32099. Washington, D.C.: January 5, 2005. 

Joint Committee on Taxation: 

The Impact of International Tax Reform: Background and Selected Issues 
Relating to U.S. International Tax Rules and the Competitiveness of 
U.S. Businesses. JCX-22-06. Washington, D.C.: June 21, 2006. 

Options to Improve Tax Compliance and Reform Tax Expenditures. JCS-02- 
05. Washington, D.C.: January 27, 2005. 

The U.S. International Tax Rules: Background, Data, and Selected Issues 
Relating to the Competitiveness of U.S.-Based Business Operations. JCX- 
67-03. Washington, D.C.: July 3, 2003. 

Background Materials on Business Tax Issues Prepared for the House 
Committee on Ways and Means Tax Policy Discussion Series. JCX-23-02. 
Washington, D.C.: April 4, 2002. 

U.S. Department of the Treasury: 

Report to The Congress on Depreciation Recovery Periods and Methods. 
Washington, D.C.: July 2000. 

Integration of The Individual and Corporate Tax Systems: Taxing 
Business Income Once. Washington, D.C.: January 1992. 

President's Advisory Panel on Federal Tax Reform: 

Simple, Fair, and Pro-Growth: Proposals to Fix America's Tax System. 
Washington, D.C.: November 2005. 

[End of section] 

Appendix II: Descriptions of Alternative Tax Systems: 

Over the past decade, several proposals for fundamental tax reform have 
been put forward. These proposals would significantly change tax rates, 
the tax base, and the level of tax (whether taxes are collected from 
individuals, businesses, or both). Some of the proposals would replace 
the federal income tax with some type of consumption tax levied only on 
businesses. Consumption taxes levied only on businesses include retail 
sales taxes (RST) and value-added taxes (VAT). The flat tax would also 
change the tax base to consumption but include both a relatively simple 
individual tax along with a business tax. A personal consumption tax, a 
consumption tax levied primarily on individuals, has also been 
proposed. Similar changes in the level at which taxes are collected 
could be made while retaining an income tax base. This appendix 
provides a brief description of several of these proposals. 

National Retail Sales Tax: 

The consumption tax that Americans are most familiar with is the retail 
sales tax, which in many states, is levied when goods or services are 
purchased at the retail level. The RST is a consumption tax because 
only goods purchased by consumers are taxed, and sales to businesses, 
including sales of investment goods, are generally exempt from tax. In 
contrast to an income tax, then, income that is saved is not taxed 
until it is used for consumption. Under a national RST, different tax 
rates could be applied to different goods, and the sale of some goods 
could carry a zero tax rate (exemption). However, directly taxing 
different individuals at different rates for the same good would be 
very difficult. 

Consumption Value-Added Tax: 

A consumption VAT, which like the RST, is a business-level consumption 
tax levied directly on the purchase of goods and services. The two 
taxes differ in the manner in which the tax is collected and paid. In 
contrast to a retail sales tax, sales of goods and services to 
consumers and to businesses are taxable under a VAT. However, 
businesses can either deduct the amount of their purchases of goods and 
services from other businesses (under a subtraction VAT) or can claim a 
credit for tax paid on purchases from other businesses (under a credit 
VAT). Under either method, sales between businesses do not generate net 
tax liability under a VAT because the amount included in the tax base 
by businesses selling goods is equal to the amount deducted by the 
business purchasing goods. The only sales that generate net revenue for 
the government are sales between businesses and consumers, which is the 
same case as the RST. 

Income Value-Added Tax: 

An income VAT would move the taxation of wage income to the business 
level as well. No individual returns would be necessary, so the burden 
of complying with the tax law would be eliminated for individuals. An 
income VAT would not allow businesses to deduct dividends, interest, or 
wages, so the income VAT remitted by businesses would include tax on 
these types of income. Calculations would not have to be made for 
different individuals, which would simplify tax administration and 
compliance burdens but not allow for treating different individuals 
differently. 

Flat Tax: 

The flat tax was developed in the early 1980s by economists Robert Hall 
and Alvin Rabushka.[Footnote 28] The Hall-Rabushka flat tax proposal 
includes both an individual tax and a business tax. As described by 
Hall and Rabushka, the flat tax is a modification of a VAT; the 
modifications make the tax more progressive (less regressive) than a 
VAT. In particular, the business tax base is designed to be the same as 
that of a VAT, except that businesses are allowed to deduct wages and 
retirement income paid out as well as purchases from other businesses. 
Wage and retirement income is then taxed when received by individuals 
at the same rate as the business tax rate. By including this individual-
level tax as well as the business tax, standard deductions can be made 
available to individuals. Individuals with less wage and retirement 
income than the standard deduction amounts would not owe any tax. 

Personal Consumption Tax: 

A personal consumption tax would look much like a personal income tax. 
The major difference between the two is that under the consumption tax, 
taxpayers would include all income received, amounts borrowed, and cash 
flows received from the sale of assets, and then deduct the amount they 
saved. The remaining amount would be a measure of the taxpayer's 
consumption over the year. When funds are withdrawn from bank accounts, 
or stocks or bonds are sold, both the original amount saved and 
interest earned are taxable because they are available for consumption. 
If withdrawn funds are reinvested in another qualified account or in 
stock or bonds, the taxable amount of the withdrawal would be offset by 
the deduction for the same amount that is reinvested. While the 
personal consumption tax would look like a personal income tax, the tax 
base would be the same as an RST. Instead of collecting tax on each 
sale of consumer products at the business level, a personal consumption 
tax would tax individuals annually on the sum of all their purchases of 
consumption goods. Because it is an individual-level tax, different tax 
rates could be applied to different individuals so that the tax could 
be made more progressive, and other taxpayer characteristics, such as 
family size, could be taken into account if desired.[Footnote 29] 

FOOTNOTES 

[1] See the explanation below for how these percentages were estimated 
and why we could not estimate them in terms of percent of taxed paid. 

[2] These criteria are also discussed at greater length in GAO, 
Understanding the Tax Reform Debate: Background, Criteria, & Questions, 
GAO-05-1009SP (Washington, D.C.: September 2005). 

[3] Limited liability companies can elect to be taxed as C 
corporations, partnerships, or as "disregarded entities." Under the 
last option the company's income and expenses are simply attributed to 
its parent corporation. 

[4] Also, marginal rates are higher over limited income ranges to 
recapture the benefits of the rates below 35 percent. In addition, 
present law imposes an alternative minimum tax (AMT) on corporations to 
the extent that their minimum tax liability exceeds their regular tax 
liability. In general, the AMT applies a lower tax rate to a broader 
tax base. Specifically, the regular tax base is increased for AMT 
purposes by adding back certain items treated as tax preferences and 
disallowing certain deductions and credits. 

[5] Individuals may also pay tax under the alternative minimum tax 
(AMT). The base of this tax equals regular taxable income, plus the 
value of various tax items, including personal exemptions and certain 
itemized deductions that are added back into the base. This AMT income 
base is then reduced by a substantial exemption and then taxed at a 
rate of 26 percent or 28 percent, depending on the taxpayer's income 
level. Taxpayers compare their AMT tax liabilities to their regular tax 
liabilities and pay the greater of the two. 

[6] Given the time frame available for preparing this statement we 
could not obtain the detailed data we would need to estimate the 
average rates of tax applied to business-source and non-business-source 
income. Consequently, we have not tried to estimate the percent of 
individual income tax attributable to business-source income. 

[7] Additional information about GAO's long-term fiscal simulations, 
assumptions, data, and charts can be found at [Hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov/special.pubs/longterm/]. 

[8] Statutory and effective tax rates are not necessarily the same. An 
effective tax rate, which is often lower--even substantially lower-- 
than the statutory rate, measures the amount of tax that a corporation 
actually pays on a dollar of its economic income, when all aspects of 
the tax (deductions, credits, deferrals, etc.) are taken into account. 

[9] Although it is difficult to estimate effective tax rates for broad 
categories of assets with precision, the estimates from one recent 
study showing the marginal effective tax rates on corporate investment, 
noncorporate investments, and owner-occupied housing to be 32 percent, 
18 percent, and 2 percent, respectively, suggest the potential 
magnitude of the distortions. See Jane Gravelle, "The Corporate Tax: 
Where Has It Been and Where Is It Going?" National Tax Journal, vol. 
57, no. 4 (2004): 903-23. 

[10] See Jane G. Gravelle, Capital Income Tax Revisions and Effective 
Tax Rates, Congressional Research Service Report RL32099 (Washington, 
D.C.: Jan. 5, 2005); and U.S. Department of the Treasury, Report to The 
Congress on Depreciation Recovery Periods and Methods (Washington, 
D.C.: July 2000). 

[11] For a more detailed discussion of these issues see U.S. Department 
of the Treasury, Integration of the Individual and Corporate Tax 
Systems: Taxing Business Income Once (Washington, D.C.: January 1992). 

[12] Recent legislation has, at least temporarily, reduced and 
equalized the tax rates on dividends and realized capital gains. These 
changes have both reduced the extent of double taxation and the extent 
to which capital gains are favored over dividends. Capital gains still 
receive some preferred treatment because of the tax deferral. 

[13] See relevant discussions in Joint Committee on Taxation, The 
Impact of International Tax Reform: Background and Selected Issues 
Relating to U.S. International Tax Rules and the Competitiveness of 
U.S. Businesses, JCX-22-06 (Washington, D.C.: June 21, 2006); CBO, 
Effects of Adopting a Value-Added Tax, (Washington, D.C.: February 
1992); Brumbaugh, David L., Federal Business Taxation: The Current 
System, Its Effects, and Options for Reform, Congressional Research 
Service report RL33171 (Washington, D.C.: December 20, 2005); and Eric 
Toder, Assistant Deputy Secretary (Tax Analysis), U.S. Department of 
Treasury, Testimony before the Senate Budget Committee, February 22, 
1995. 

[14] Although this information reporting increases the compliance 
burden on businesses, it does enable IRS to enforce tax compliance by 
wage earners and investors at lower cost. This reduction in 
administrative costs, which are paid out of the federal budget, means 
that taxes are slightly lower than they otherwise would have to be. 

[15] See GAO, Tax Policy: Summary of Estimates of the Costs of the 
Federal Tax System, GAO-05-878 (Washington, D.C.: Aug. 26, 2005). 

[16] Overall, IRS estimated a gross tax gap of $345 billion for tax 
year 2001. It further estimated that eventually $55 billion of the tax 
gap would be recovered through late payments and enforcement actions, 
resulting in a net tax gap of $290 billion. The tax gap includes 
underreporting of taxes on tax returns, underpayment of taxes reported 
on returns, or nonfiling, which is when taxpayers fail to file returns 
on time or altogether. 

[17] The amount of the business income tax gap attributed to individual 
taxpayers could be greater than $109 billion. Although IRS estimated 
the tax gap for individual income tax underpayment and nonfiling ($23 
billion and $25 billion, respectively, for tax year 2001), it did not 
estimate to what extent such noncompliance was attributed to business 
income, as opposed to nonbusiness income such as salaries and wages. 
Also, IRS estimated the tax gap that arises from individuals 
misreporting tax deductions and credits, but does not estimate what 
portion of the misreporting was from business-related deductions and 
credits. 

[18] In a 2003 testimony, we reported that IRS had identified 27 kinds 
of abusive shelter transactions--called listed transactions--promoted 
to corporations and others. As of September 2006, IRS's Web site lists 
31 such listed transactions. IRS also had a number of other 
transactions that had to be reported to IRS and may have had some 
characteristics of abusive shelters but were not, and possibly never 
would be, listed. 

[19] For additional information on how differences in the structures of 
both income and consumption taxes can affect tax administration and 
taxpayer compliance burdens, see Tax Administration: Potential Impact 
of Alternative Taxes on Taxpayers and Administrators, GAO/GGD-98-37 
(Washington, D.C.: Jan. 14, 1998). 

[20] For a further discussion of these issues, see GAO/GGD-98-37. 

[21] See app. II for brief descriptions of each of these types of 
taxes. 

[22] In cases where a U.S. corporation earns income in a country with a 
higher income tax than in the United States that corporation earns a 
larger tax credit than is needed to offset the U.S. tax owed on that 
foreign-source income. The difference between the foreign tax credit 
earned on a specific amount of foreign-source income and the amount of 
U.S. tax owed on that income is known as an excess foreign tax credit. 

[23] The disadvantage that U.S. corporations have under the current 
system is one reason why some U.S. multinational businesses have 
undergone "corporate inversions," whereby their parent corporations 
have changed their place of incorporation from the United States to a 
foreign country. 

[24] This time the mechanism would operate in the reverse direction-- 
the tax on U.S. exports would decrease the foreign demand for those 
products, leading to a drop in the value of the dollar. That decline in 
the dollar's value would reverse the tax-induced increase in the price 
of U.S. exports and would raise the price of imports into the United 
States, offsetting any price advantage they had gained from being 
exempt from the consumption tax. 

[25] For further discussion of transition issues see GAO-05-1009SP. 

[26] GAO-05-1009SP. 

[27] See GAO-05-1009SP for further discussion on the relationship 
between efficiency and economic growth. 

[28] See Robert E. Hall and Alvin Rabushka, The Flat Tax, 2nd ed. 
(Stanford, Calif.: Hoover Press, 1995). 

[29] To tax certain types of consumption that can occur within a 
business, such as fringe benefits or the personal use of goods such as 
cars, many personal consumption tax proposals also include a business- 
level "cash flow" tax. Investment would be expensed under such a tax to 
ensure that the overall tax base would be consumption. 

GAO's Mission: 

The Government Accountability Office, the audit, evaluation and 
investigative arm of Congress, exists to support Congress in meeting 
its constitutional responsibilities and to help improve the performance 
and accountability of the federal government for the American people. 
GAO examines the use of public funds; evaluates federal programs and 
policies; and provides analyses, recommendations, and other assistance 
to help Congress make informed oversight, policy, and funding 
decisions. GAO's commitment to good government is reflected in its core 
values of accountability, integrity, and reliability. 

Obtaining Copies of GAO Reports and Testimony: 

The fastest and easiest way to obtain copies of GAO documents at no 
cost is through GAO's Web site (www.gao.gov). Each weekday, GAO posts 
newly released reports, testimony, and correspondence on its Web site. 
To have GAO e-mail you a list of newly posted products every afternoon, 
go to www.gao.gov and select "Subscribe to Updates." 

Order by Mail or Phone: 

The first copy of each printed report is free. Additional copies are $2 
each. A check or money order should be made out to the Superintendent 
of Documents. GAO also accepts VISA and Mastercard. Orders for 100 or 
more copies mailed to a single address are discounted 25 percent. 
Orders should be sent to: 

U.S. Government Accountability Office 441 G Street NW, Room LM 
Washington, D.C. 20548: 

To order by Phone: Voice: (202) 512-6000 TDD: (202) 512-2537 Fax: (202) 
512-6061: 

To Report Fraud, Waste, and Abuse in Federal Programs: 

Contact: 

Web site: www.gao.gov/fraudnet/fraudnet.htm E-mail: fraudnet@gao.gov 
Automated answering system: (800) 424-5454 or (202) 512-7470: 

Congressional Relations: 

Gloria Jarmon, Managing Director, JarmonG@gao.gov (202) 512-4400 U.S. 
Government Accountability Office, 441 G Street NW, Room 7125 
Washington, D.C. 20548: 

Public Affairs: 

Paul Anderson, Managing Director, AndersonP1@gao.gov (202) 512-4800 
U.S. Government Accountability Office, 441 G Street NW, Room 7149 
Washington, D.C. 20548: